BEFORE THE ILLINOIS POLLUTION CONTROL BOARD
IN THE MATTER OF:
)
1
PROPOSED NEW 35 1LL.ADM.CODE PART 225
)
PCB R06-25
CONTROL OF EMISSIONS FROM
)
Rulemaking
-
Air
LARGE COMBUSTION SOURCES
NOTICE OF FILING
Dorothy Gunn, Clerk
Illinois Pollution Control Board
James R. Thompson Center
Suite 11-500
100 West Randolph
Chicago, Illinois 60601
Persons included on the
ATTACHED SERVICE LIST
PLEASE TAKE NOTICE that we have today filed with the Office of the Clerk of the
Pollution Control Board
MIDWEST GENERATION'S POST-HEARING COMNIENTS:
ADDITIONAL INFORMATION.
ISI
~
h
6'
&3&
h
Kathleen C. Bassi
Dated: September 15,2006
Sheldon
A. Zahel
Kathleen C. Bassi
Stephen
J. Bonebrake
Joshua
R. More
Glenna Gilbert
SCHIFF
HARDIN, LLP
6600 Sears Tower
233 South Wacker Drive
Chicago, Illinois 60606
3 12-258-5500
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
BEFORE THE ILLINOIS POLLUTION CONTROL BOARD
IN THE MATTER OF:
1
)
PROPOSED NEW 35 1LL.ADM.CODE PART 225
)
PCB R06-25
CONTROL OF EMISSIONS FROM
1
LARGE COMBUSTION SOURCES
)
MIDWEST GENERATION'S POST-HEARING COMMENTS:
ADDITIONAL INFORMATION
NOW COMES Participant MIDWEST GENERATION, LLC. by and through its
attorneys, SCHIFF
HARDIN, LLP, pursuant to 35 I11.Adm.Code
5
102.108, and offers the
following information as requested at hearing as comments for the Record of the
above-
captioned proposed rule:
1.
Mr. William DePriest was asked to provide information specific to Illinois
regarding the number of upgrade projects for electrostatic precipitators
("ESPs") involving
Sargent
&
Lundy as further response to pre-filed Question 29 from the Illinois Environmental
Protection Agency ("Agency"). Chicago Transcript
("C Tr."), p. 1216 (August 18,2006, a.m.)
Mr. DePriest reports that Sargent
&
Lundy has been involved in 21 retrofits of whole
precipitators to existing units, 20 precipitator performance improvement projects, and five
structural examinations and modifications at Illinois companies.
2.
Mr. James Marehetti was asked to provide a breakdown of the categories included
in his conclusion that the Illinois mercury rule would cost companies $200 million per year,
annualized costs as further response to Question
7 of the pre-filed questions submitted by the
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Agency. C Tr., p. 1302 (August 18,2006, p.m.) Appended hereto as Attachment 1 is a table
breaking
down those costs.
3.
Mr. Marchetti has also provided additional information relative to Exhibits 119
and 120, appended hereto as Attachments 2 and
3; respectively.
4.
Dr. Peter Chapman was asked for the internet address of the Metropolitan Water
Reclamation District's information that served as the basis for his calculations of the amounts of
mercury in stormwater runoff as further response to the Agency's pre-filed Question 5. C Tr., p.
27 (August 22,2006, a.m.) That address is
~www.mwrd.org/RD/iepa-reports.htm#Water
Quality Data Reports>.
5.
Dr. Gail Charnley was asked to provide articles regarding emissions trading. C
Tr., p. 1679 (August 22,2006, p.m.) Appended hereto as Attachment 4 is Byron Swift,
Emissions Trading and Hot Spots: A Review ofthe Major Programs,
BNA (May 7,2004).
Appended hereto as Attachment
5 is Byron Swift,
Command Without Control: Why Cap-und-
Trade Should Replace Rate Standards for Regional Pollutants:
3 1 ELR 10330.
6.
Mr. Ayres asked Mr.
Krish Vijayaraghavan to provide a calculation of a 90
percentile confidence levels for the point estimates.
See
C Tr., pp. 1500-1502. Mr.
Vijayaraghavan indicated that he would have to look into whether that could be done. C Tr., p.
1502. Mr. Vijayaraghavan has examined that question further and determined that the type of
analysis that Mr. Ayres appears to have requested is not applicable to the type of information that
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Mr. Vijayaraghavan provided at hearing. Therefore, we have no additional information on this
point.
Respectfully submitted,
MIDWEST GENERATION,
LLC
by:
One of Its Attorneys
Dated: September 15,2006
Sheldon A.
Zabel
Kathleen C. Bassi
Stephen J. Bonebrake
Joshua R. More
Glenna L. Gilbert
SCI-IIFF HARDN, LLP
6600 Sears Tower
233 South Wacker Drive
Chicago, Illinois 60606
3 12-258-5500
Fax: 3 12-258-5600
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Follow-UP information for Question
7
Dosed t@ Mr. Marchletti
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
FOLLOW-UP INFORMATION
ON
QUESTION
7
CUMULATIVE ANNUALIZED COMPLIANCE COSTS FOR
SO2,
NOx
AND MERCURY BY COST COMPONENTS: 2009
-
2018
(billions
of
2006
$)
Rule
Ann
Cap-Tech
Ann-Fuel
Ann-fixed
Ann-var
Allow
Pur
Allow
Sales
Total
Cost
CAlR
SO2
1.03
-0.06
0.12
0.25
0.77
-0.20
1.91
NOx
0.38
0.00
0.01
0.17
0.30
-0.21
0.65
CAMR
0.05
0.00
0.01
0.11
0.41
-0.04
0.54
TOTAL
1.46
-0.06
0.14
0.53
1.48
-0.45
3.10
IL-CAIR
SO2
1.01
-0.03
0.12
0.25
0.73
-0.22
1.85
NOx
0.36
0.00
0.01
0.16
0.30
-0.21
0.62
IL-Hg
2.08
0.00
0.11
0.44
0
0
2.63
TOTAL
3.45
-0.03
0.24
0.85
1.03
-0.43
5.10
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Attachment
2
Additiarral details for Exhibit 119
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
CAIR-CAMR Tech (Ex
-
119)
Lookup
384#7
384#8
6016#1
6017#1
85W1
85W2
85W3
861#1
861#2
864#3
867#8
87Wl
876#2
879#5
87W
8838
884#4
889#3
891%
898#5
9631
963#2
9633
976#4
SYSTEM
UNIT-NAME
so2-tech
Midwest Generations EME LLC
JOLIET
7
Midwest Generations EME LLC
JOLIET
8
Ameren Energy Resources
Generating
Co
DUCK CREEK
1
Ameren Energy
Generating
Co
NEWrON
1
DFGD
Ameren Energy Resources
Generating
Co
ED
EDWARDS
1
Ameren Energy Resources
Generating
Co
ED
EDWARDS 2
Ameren Energy Resources
Generating
Co
ED
EDWARDS 3
Ameren
Energy
Generating Co
COFFEEN 1
WFGDIFS
Ameren Energy
Generating Co
COFFEEN 2
WFGDIFS
Ameren Energy
Generating Co
MEREDOSIA
3
Midwest Generations EME
LLC
CRAWFORD
8
Kincaid
(Dominion)
KINCAID 1
Kincaid (Dominion)
KlNCAlD
2
M
awest
Generat
ons
tME
LLC
POWERTON
5
M
dwesl General
ons
EME
LLC
POWtHlON
6
Midwest Generations EME
LLC
Midwest Generations EME
LLC
Dynegy Midwest
Generation Inc
Dynegy Midwest Generation
Inc
Dynegy Midwest Generation
Inc
Springfield
City
of
Springfield City
of
Springfield
City
of
Southern
Illinois
Power
Coop
WAUKEGAN 8
WILL
COUNTY 4
BALDWIN
3
HAVANA 6
WOOD RIVER
(IL)
5
DALLMAN 1
DALLMAN 2
DALLMAN 3
MARION
(IL)
4
so2tech-year
nox-tech
nox-tech-year
S7MO
2010
SNCR
SNCR
S7MO
2010
S7MO
2010
S7MO
SNCR
SNCR
S7MO
S7MO
SCR
SCR
SNCR
SNCR
SNCR
2009
S7MO
2009
S7MO
2009
S7MO
2009
S7MO
2009
hg-tech
hg-tech-year
Namplate
ACI
201 1
660
ACI
2010
660
441
ACI
2010
617.4
363.8
388.9
616.5
ACI
2010
239.3
358.1
659.5
659.5
892.8
HACI
2017
.
892.8
355.3
598.4
ACI
2016
634.5
HACl
2010
488
387.6
90
90
207
173
Note:
1. The
Nevdon
1
and
Coffeen
1
8
2 FGD
systems
are planned
for
CAIR
compliance
and
are not
projected
by our
modeling, but
their compliance costs have been included
in
our
CAIR costs,
as well
as
their emissions.
2.
Baldwin
1
-
3
and Havana 6 DFGD
systems have
been
included
in
our modeling of
emissions,
but
no CAIR
costs
have been assigned
because
they are a
result
of
Dynegy's
co
decree. These four FGD ystesms
will
be
installed
between 2009 and 2012.
The
3
existing
SCRs
at
Baldwin
1
8
2
and Havana
6
are to
operate year-round
due to
the
consent
I
They
have been
included
in
our
modeling of emissions
but no
CAlR costs have been
assigned.
3.
The existing
FGDs
at
Duck
Creek, Marion
4 and
Dallman
1-3
are
not
listed
above but
have been included
in
our modeling of
emissions.
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Attachment
3
Additional information for Exhibit
12Ci
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
CAIR-IL
Rule Tech
(Ex
-
120)
Lookup
384#7
384#8
6016#1
6017#1
6017#2
85W1
85W2
856#3
861#1
861#2
8633
863#4
864#1
864#2
864#3
867#7
867#8
874#6
876#1
876#2
879#5
879#6
8836
8837
883#8
884#1
884#2
884#3
884#4
88W19
887#1
887#2
887#3
687#4
887#5
887%
889#3
891#6
892#1
892#2
897#2
897#ST1
898#4
SYSTEM
UNIT-NAME
Midwest
Generations EME LLC
JOLIET
7
Midwest
Generations
EME
LLC
JOLIET
8
Ameren Energy Resources
Generating
Co.
DUCK
CREEK
I
Ameren
Energy
Generating
Co
NEWTON
1
Ameren
Energy
Generating
Co
NEWTON
2
Ameren Energy Resources
Generating
Co.
ED EDWARDS
1
Amerer
Energy
Resources
Genera!
ng Co
CD
EDWARDS
7
Amerel
Flerov
Keso~rces
Generbl
no
Co
Fl)
FDWARDS
3
",
-
Ameren Energy
Generating Co
COFFEEN
1
Ameren
tnergy
Gcnerai~ng
Co
COFFCEN
2
Ailelen
Enerav
Generat
no
Co
HUTSONVIL
1
F
3
Ameien
~ner;;
ene era tin;
Co
HUTSONVILLE
4
A~neren
~nerrj~
~enera1,nG
Co
MEREDOSIA
'
Ameren
Encrov
Generatina
Co
MERCDOSIA
2
-.
-
Ameren
Energy
Generating
Co
MEREDOSIA
3
M~dwesr
Generat4ons
CMC
LLC
CRAWFORD
7
Mdwesl
General
ons
FMt
L
.C
CRAWFOHO
8
Midwest
Generations EME
LLC
Kincaid (Dominion)
Kincaid
(Dominion)
Midwest Generations EME LLC
Midwest
Generations
EME
LLC
Midwest
Generations
EME
LLC
Midwest
Generations EME LLC
Midwest Generations
EME LLC
M~dwesr
Generar
ons
FMC LLC
Mldwesl
Generar
ons
EME LLC
Midwest
Generations EME
LLC
Midwest
Generations
EME
LLC
Midwest
Generations EME LLC
EEI
EEI
EEI
EEI
EEI
EEI
Dynegy Midwest
Generation
Inc
Dynegy Midwest
Generation
Inc
Dynegy Midwest
Generation
Inc
Dynegy
Midwest Generation
Inc
Dynegy
Midwest Generation Inc
Dynegy
Midwest Generation Inc
Dynegy
Midwest Generation
Inc
JOLIET
6
KlNCAlD
1
KlNCAlD
2
POWERTON
5
POWERTON
6
WAUKEGAN
6
WAUKEGAN
7
WAUKEGAN
8
WlLL
COUNlY
1
WlLL
COUNTY
2
WlLL
COUNTY
3
WlLL
COUNTY
4
FISK
19
JOPPA
1
JOPPA
2
JOPPA
3
JOPPA
4
JOPPA
5
JOPPA
6
BALDWIN
3
HAVANA
6
HENNEPIN
1
HENNEPIN
2
VERMILION
2
VERMILION
1
WOOD
RIVER
(IL)
4
S7MO
2009
DFGD
2010
SNCR
2009
SNCR
2009
S7MO
2009
WFGDIFS
2010
S7MO
2009
WFGDIFS
2010
S7MO
2009
SNCR
2009
S7MO
2009
S7MO
2009
SCR
2009
SCR
2009
SNCR
2009
hgfech
hgtech-year
COHP
2009
COHP
2009
HACl
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
COHP
2009
FF
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
FF
2009
HCOHP
2009
HACI
2009
HCOHP
2009
COHP
2009
HACl
2009
HCOHP
2009
FF
2009
COHP
2009
HACl
2009
HACI
2009
HCOHP
2009
HACl
2009
HACl
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
COHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HCOHP
2009
HACl
2009
HACl
2009
HACI
2009
HCOHP
2009
HACl
2013
HACl
2013
ACI
2009
Namplate
660
660
441
617.4
617.4
136
280.5
363.8
388.9
616.5
75
75
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
CAIR-IL
Rule
Tech (Ex
-
120)
Lookup
SYSTEM
UNIT-NAME
so2-tech
so2fech-year
nox-tech
nox-tech-year
hg-tech
hg-tech-year
Namplate
898#5
Dynegy
Midwest
Generation
lnc
WOOD
RIVER
(IL)
5
SNCR
2009
COHP
2009
387.6
963#1
Springfield City
of
DALLMAN
1
S7MO
2009
90.2
963#2
Springfield
City
of
DALLMAN 2
S7MO
2009
90.2
963#3
Springfield City of
DALLMAN 3
S7MO
2009
207.3
976#4
Southern
Illinois
Power Coop
MARION
(IL)
4
S7MO
2009
173
Note:
1. The Newton 1
and
Coffeen
1
8
2 FGD systems are
planned for
CAlR
compliance
and
are
not
projected
by
our
modeling,
but their compliance costs have been included
in
our
CAlR costs,
as well
as
their
emissions.
2.
Baldwin
1
-
3 and Havana
6
DFGD svstems
have been included
in
our
modelino
of emissions, but
no CAlR
costs have
been
assianed
because
thev
are a
result of
Dvneav's consent
.
-.
decree. These four FGD ystesms
ill
be
installed between
2009 and
2012.
he
3
existing
SCRS
at
Baldwin
1
8
2
and
Havana
6-are
to
operate
year-round
due
to
the
consent decree.
They
have been
included
in
our
modeling
of emissions
but
no
CAlR costs have been
assigned.
3.
The
existing
FGDs
at
Duck
Creek,
Marion
4
and
Dallman
1-3
are not
listed
above
but have been
included in
our
modeling
of emissions.
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Attachment 4
Emissions Trading and Hot Spots: A Review of
the Major
Proerams
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
ENVIRONMENT
REPORTER*
I)
4,.
I
I
Reproduced with permission from Environment Re-
porter,
Vol. 35, No. 19, 05!07!2004. Copyright
0
2004
by The Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. (800-372-1033)
http:!/www.bna.oorn
EMISSIONS TRADING
This report examines whether the major U.S. emissions trading programs for air pollut-
ants have contributed to elevated emissions concentrations in specific geographic areas, or
pollution "hot spots." Assessment of the actual performance of these programs shows that
none has resulted in a regional shift of emissions, and all trading programs examined have
led to proportionately greater emissions reductions from the larger sources. Overall, the
data from the programs reviewed indicate that trading has not created geographic hot spots
and, in promoting reductions at the largest plants, has smoothed out pollutant emissions in-
stead of concentrating them.
Emissions Trading and Hot Spots: A Review of the Major Programs
I. Introduction
T
his report examines whether the major U.S. emis-
sions trading programs for air pollutants have
cnn-
tributed to elevated emissions concentrations in
specific areas, also known as pollution "hot spots." En-
vironmentalists have been concerned about the poten-
tial for emissions trading programs to create such con-
centrations or hot spots, as have advocates of environ-
mental justice, who have voiced such concerns as a
basis for opposing emissions trading programs.'
This report is the first to comprehensively examine
the actual emissions data from the major emissions
'See,
e.g.,
Moore,
Cuitis,
Marketing Failure: Tke Experi-
ence with Air Pollution Trading in
the United States 34
ELR
10,281
(March 2004); Johnson, Stephen:
Economics
us.
Equity
Do Market-based Environmental Reforms Exacerbate Envi-
ronmental Justice?
56
Wash.
&
Lee L. Rev. I I1 (1999).
COPYRIGHT" 2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS. INC., WASHINGTON, D.C. 20037
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
trading programs, which primarily affect emissions of
sulfur dioxide and nitrogen oxides from power plants:
8
Phase I of the SO, Acid Rain Program (1995-
1999);
Phase
I1
of the SO, Acid Rain Program (start-
ing in 2000); and
rn
Ozone Transport Commission (OTC) NOx
Budget Program (1999-2002).
In addition to these three major emissions cap and al-
lowance trading programs, we also examine
NOx credit
trading programs inseveral states.
This report first examines the
hot spot issue from a
regional perspective, addressing the chief concern
voiced at
the initiation of the acid rain SO, trading pro-
.
eram:
,
whether the increased flexibility allowed by trad-
In); \v,,uld re.:ilt
In
di-proponionorel\ greater emis>ion
riom \I~d\ves:ern ?uurrc.>, aiiec:rln:: hc-nslli\,e ecosy\-
rein, In C,)\vnwlllu dren, tc, the enit. For the
01C
SOX
program we examine the data by state to determine
whether
. . . . . . . .
there
.
were in fact reeional
"
shifts of emissions
with trading.
Secondly, we attempt to determine the effects of trad-
ins
~-~-
on
-~~
a
-
more
~~
local level bv examining ~lant-level data
to see whether the trading"programs Gsed reductions
homogeneously with regard to plant size, or caused
dis-
~ro~ohionate
emissions reductions at plants with rela-
iiveiv hieh or low emissions
TL~ ~Ybjective evaluation of the hot spot issue is im-
portant because emissions trading programs create the
bpportunity to attain poilution reduction goals at lower
cost through a market-based implementation
mecha-
ni~m.~
The cap-and-trade programs combine a strin-
gent environmental standard-the
capwith a very
high-integrity trading system that increases compliance
options. This creates efficiency, and the major cap-and-
trade programs have been credited with substantially
lowering compliance costs in comparison to traditional
rate-based
standard^.^ By lowering costs, the programs
can benefit the environment hv ailowine ~oliticiins to
trade
nrograms create a fundamentally better regula-
vation,
tom
"
sheik
"
creates
for
continuois
reeional
-
nollutants
drivers
thai~romotes
for cleaner produc-
Cnno-
tion, and are easily enforced
'
These benefits could he
See,
e.g., Tietenberg, T.H., Emissions Doding: An Exer-
cise in Reforming Pollution Policy (Resources for the
Future,
Washington, D.C., 1985); Harrison, David, Tradable Permits
for Air
Pollution Control, in 1~renx.moti~~
Ymoox
or EWI~ON-
MENTAL NUU RLSOURCE
ECONOMICS
2001 (2001).
"
See, A. Denny Elleiman et al., Wis
Fan
CLW
AIR:
THE
U.S.
Aciu bin Pnoc-
(2000); Cu& Carlson, Dallas Burlraw,
Maureen Cropper, and Karen L. Palmer, Sulfur Dioxide Con-
trol by Eiectric Utilities: What Are the Gains from Trade7108
Journal of Political Economy 1292 (2000).
'
Authors point out that cap-and-trade programs guarantee
emissions reductions, permanently cap emissions, create zero
growth in emissions from new sources, allow greater scope for
compliance through cleaner fuels and clean production tech-
nologies, increase compliance levels to virtually 100 percent,
and greatly lower compliance costs. See generally,
Elleman,
Denny, Paul Joskow and David Harrison, Emissions Trading in
the
U.S.:
Experience, Lessons, and Considerations
for
Green-
house Gases, Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Arling-
ton,
Va. (May, 2003) [available at http:/lwww.pewclimate.orgj;
Swift, Byron, How Environmental
Laws
Work: An Analysis of
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT
"
2004 BY THE BUREAU OF
lost if inaccurate perceptions about trading systems dis-
courage their use where appropriate.
II.
Emissions Trading
-
Systems
-
Emissions trading programs provide flexibility to
regulated sources that must meet a common environ-
mental standard. Trading systems allow sources that
emit pollution below an allocation level or an environ-
mental standard to sell or transfer their reductions to
other sources, which may then emit above the level or
standard. The flexibility afforded
by trading reduces
comnliance costs hv allowine sources that can reduce
regards to
eniissions concentrations or h'bt spots.
No assessment of emissions trading can be done
without understanding its three fundamentally different
forms-emissions
can and allowance trading
~,
(can-and-
. .
lrnde) program, rlili\lonb awrdging plugrnn~>. and
project bahed emlrions rred~l program\ \!"\I
oi (,ur
analysis deals with the major cap-and-trade systems,
which both reduce emissions and create a fundamen-
tally
difieren~ compliance ;q,lem iur \vurccs than lrn
ditiunal recl~i~r,log?.l,itsed r.ilc sr:~ndard~ l'l>cx! al%~
have a very higGintegrity allowance trading system
that. because of the can.
. .
assures a decline in total
emis-
\ion; ir,,m aifccted ouncs :\\.crJglng and cl-cdlr
\ys-
rem. however.
drc
gr~rred unro cxlhr~ng compliance
systems and differ from cap-and-trade programs in
manv
wavs. These three oroerams
. .,
differ so simificantlv
in rhcir &n\.ironrnenral .ind ecutlunlic eifeL.l..'!h:il
ihc?
illould be conbidered distinct r\.pci of regularor\ pro
grams and not lumped together as trading~programs.
A. Emissions Gau and Allowance Trading
-
Promams
-
\losr vl our analysis rilnrcrn\ the Acid l(;iin I'rogr.in1
2nd rhe So~lhcasrcrn
0
I
C'
SOX I'rocmnl. I~urh
cxp-
and-trade programs. Under this approach, an overall
emissions cap is established over a large region, creat-
ing a strict regulatory standard that permanently re-
duces emissions. All affected sources are then allocated
allowance^.^ which renresent their share of the total
cap, and can trade
allobances with each other for com-
pliance purposes. New sources are typically not pro-
the Utility Sector's Response to Regulation of Nitrogen Oxides
and Sulfur Dioxide Under the Clean
Air Act, 14 Tulane Envtl.
L.J. 309 (Summer 2001) [available at http:/lwww.epa.gov/
aimarkets/aniclesAndex.htmlj
See generally, U.S. EPA, Clearing the Air: Re Truth
About Capping and Trading Emissions. EPA
430F-02-009
may 2002); Ellerrnan, A. Denny, David Hamson, Emissions
Trading in the US.: Experience, Lessons, and Considerations
for Greenhouse Gases. Pew Center for Global Climate Change
(Arlington,
Va., May 2003); Haites, Erik, An Emerging Market
for the Environment:
A Guide to Emissions Trading
(L.N.
En-
vironment Program,
2002)
[see
http://~.uccee.orgETguidei
GuideEmissiansTrading.pdfj.
This article refers to trading in this spatial sense of a
transfer of emissions tons between different sources and ex-
amines its effects with regards to emissions concentrations.
The spatial trading of allowances or credits is to he distin-
guished from temporal trading, such
as
banking, which has the
effect of moving a ton of emissions from one year to another.
See generally, EPA,
mree Forms of Emissions Trading.
Clean
Air Markets Update, Winter 2002.
'Each allowance typically represents one ton of a pollutant
that may be emitted in
a given year.
NATIONAL AFFAIRS. INC.. WASHINGTON, D.C.
ER
ISSN 00139211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
vided with any allowances, hut must obtain them from
existing sources, leading
to essentially a zero new
source standard.'
The cap-and-trade approach fundamentally changes
the
~,ltc-!~';\ed
reeulatorv
~r;ind;~rd\
.
svstem
.
awav
nnd'lnti,
from
an
traditional
u\.ernlI pe~~iorrnirncc
end-of-nioe
. .
I
.
' I h~lc 1)rugr~m\ h1t.e been 5ho\vn to reduce
Illc co\r, or cuml~lionce ro itall or less ~,f the COAI 01 !ra-
ditional rate-based standards. Thev can also transform
bu>i!~es, ~r,n~pli:~ntc
behavior tu\?ardr n pollution pre-
\cnrl~,u rcs1,on.e 2nd a\\.ay irom ~nsrnlling end-(11-pipe
controls, broaden and strenfihen the context for inno-
vation. ereatlv
.,
,
reduce administrative costs. and create
hlrnort I(
(J
percent r~,mpliancu.'
'
Cap-:ind-rradc pru-
grm,
31>tt
eital~lrrh an errcmcly cr~!dihle furm ui al-
lowance trading based on rigorous monitoring that has
high integrity because the cap prevents trading from
ever leading to excess emissions.
B. Emissions Credit Trading Programs
At the other end of the spectrum are credit trading
programs, which are grafted onto existing regulatory
programs, such as traditional emissions rate regula-
tions
grimi
under
in \\.hich
the Clean
suurcei
Air
unden'fike
Act. These
projerr
are
voluntarv
that ci-exrc
.
oro-
.
qu.$~~t~rr:~l~le
pi,llu!ron rcd~:rlions uvcr and uhu\.e their
CXI,IL!I/: permilred luvcls vr pas1 cnli~iions le\'elr. I'hc
sources receive credits for these reductions. which thev
may then sell or transfer to other
sourcesfor cnmpll-
ance purposes.
to other trading programs. Some of the reasons are that
there is no change in the underlying compliance sys-
tem, fewer tons are available to he traded, and more
regulatory procedures are needed, generating fewer
economic gains. Also, because credit programs are used
with
existine
..
~ermittine
.
...
Droerams
..
that tvuicallv
. .
do not
rvqulrc cui:ritr:rc~u~ ~rnisaicrn n~~~niror\,
rhcy als~ have
I?% relr~ble repolilng and rnnniroring or emisston, than
cap-and-trade programs since firms can select which
projects to present, credit trading systems have an in-
herent weakness in allowing firms to derive credit for
ant m end-of-oine
-
emissions See for examnle ax standards
such as
~easdnibly Available ~oitrol ~echiolo'gy
(RACT)
for
existing sources, Best Available Control Technology
(BACT)
for new sources, and Maximum Achievable Control Technol-
ogy
WC1) for hazardous pollutants. 42 U.S.C. 88 7SOZ(c)(l),
7475(a)(4), 7412(g)(2)(A) (1994). Rate standards have been
~
~
~~
~~~
~ - ~~ - - -~ ~~~~~
MEN+&
TEC~SNOLOCY
I~INOYA'~~ON
39 (1991): Swift. Bwn. Environ.
mental Law institute, How ~n;iron&ntal icws
hrk:
An
Analysis
of
the Utility
Sector's
Response to Regulation of h'i-
trogen Oxides and Sulfur Dioxide Under the Clean Air Act, 14
Tulane Envtl. L.J. 309 (Summer 2001) [available at http:!l
www.epa.gov/airmarkets/articles/index,html].
"For evaluations of the SO, program,
see
supra notes
3
and 4.
projects that they might have done anyway, potentially
increasing overall emissions. However, credit trading
systems may he useful when system-wide approaches,
such as cap-and-trade or averaging, are infeasible. A re-
cent analysis provides
best practices for credit pro-
grams, while noting they have lower integrity than
cap-
and-trade programs.'2
C. Emissions Averaging Programs
In between these two systems are emissions averag-
ing programs, in which a rate-based "average," or stan-
dard, is established for a group of sources. Individual
sources that emit
below the average emissions rate can
earn credits that can then he sold or
transferred to
sources that emit above the average rate. Averaging
svstems can be used either with a uniform rate standard
or
rechnulogy-habed rare standardr, nlrhough the u>e ui
ii uniform standard may promore clei~ner rechnolo-
pies.'"
A\,erdging system, ;lllo\r rradin~ ro tak~: pla,~! ;lure-
rnarlcllly bcrwt.cn covered rource~, \\.hll.h dIlo\v.~ fur
greater rrading and rhui cconornic $:din.. ,\ltll~,ugl~
ru-
tal emissions may grow over time, unlike cap-andTtrade
nroerams.
. -
all sources are included in the oroeram.
. ~,
\r
hich elitninarc\ rhe danger oi "ymin~" [he ,>ten1
rhn~ugh di-\elecr~un
01
prujcrrs rhar eulirs wirh credit
trading programs. Also, credits in averaging systems
are
..
generated throueh standard
~rotocols that do not
requrre guvernmt:nr approml 01 rndiv~du:il prujccrh.
greatly retluc~ng rnninctinrl COT\ :in11 hence r,nh;incing
economic gains.
111. Limitations and Context of an Evaluation of
Emissions Concentrations,
or Hot Spots
This naDer
. .
reviews the effect of existing. emissions
trading prugrAms ru determine ii rl~ey ha\
v
incrcas~~d
or
decreased the
c<~nccnrrariun ui pulluli~,n eml~rlun.,
Such a study essentially evaluates and compares trad-
ing
proache2
-
Dromams
. ..
rhar ach~c\.e
with other
cqui\nlenr
oossible
reductrc,nr
remiaton,
over
.
rhc
an-
.
same source>, and a> such ha> 3 number oi lirriit;iti~,n~.
discussed below. In particular, such a review should not
he confused with one of the stringency of regulation,
nor of differing needs of national versus local
reguia-
tory programs.
A. Assessing Regulatory Stringency vs. Method
The first caveat to our studv is that it does not deal
!virh rhc lc\,cl oi rringency oirvgular~vn. bvhlch ih :!pi
c;illy legialativcly dcrrrmined. k:lnlssiun.r conc.cnrrd-
tiun, or h~11 sporc ori#in~te In real-\\.~~rld
s~ruarion,,
such as the sitkg of coal-fired Dower nlants or the use
"See Environmental law institute, Emission Reduction
Credit
lkading Systems: An Overview of Recent Results and
an Assessment of Best Practices, Environmental Law Institute
(October 2002); see also Dudek, Daniel
&
John Palmisano,
Emissions Trading: Why
Is
This Thoroughbred Hobbled?, 13
Colum.
J. Envtl. L. 217 (1988).
'Wniform standards do so because they allow firms to
meet the standard by using
a cleaner technology. Technology-
based rate standards on the other hand require controls re-
gardless of how clean the technology is and
so
provide no in-
centives to install cleaner technologies.
An
example of a uni-
form standard is the fuel-neutral New Source Performance
Standard for
NOx.
40 C.F.R.
8
60.44b.
EWIRONMENT REPORTER
ISSN
00159211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
qulrlllg ~llc~qultf
pullutsnl rc'llurrlons \\,!I1 en11 ...l8,n lev-
?I, in such arcas ~t(.ru:~lly
dc,~l~ne.
:\
gu(~d cx.inlplc i rhc cue oi SO.
..
a\
[he t,ulld,ng oi
pG,hcr pl.inrr in rhc \II~\\.LcI
IO uw the rclnr~vel! high-
~Iiur
(.0:1I> (~f the rt,gion lcd 10 ele\.ared emission5 le\.-
els in that region andualso affected downwind (Eastern)
states. Initial efforts to regulate these plants under Title
I of the Clean Air
Act1* resulted primarily in the disper-
sion of pollution through tall stacks;'' SO, emissions
barely declined, falling from 17 million to 16 million
tons between 1970 and
1990.'6
The Acid Rain Program was passed in 1990 to ad-
dress this situation and mandates a 50 percent reduc-
tion in SO, emissions from 1980 baseline levels to ap-
proximately 9 million
tons.17 While EPA data shows
that the Acid Rain Program has significantly reduced
sulfur deposition and sulfate concentrations in the at-
mosphere, it also indicates that additional reductions in
sulfate deposition are still needed to assure the
recov-
erv of acidic waters and forest soils. and enhance health
henrl~r
.'
I hebe ttnding, have led 10 the inrn~ducr~on
c,i b~ll~
ln C.on$,rc~s, a> w?ll
a,
a propc~s~tl
I)? I:!':\,
rhdr
I! r lor din ucn I SO ernl.,sion\ 10
the 2 million to 3 million ton level.'Y
-
Our examination instead is of the reeulatorv method.
13
hqu~rs
a,
IO wlicth(,r, ar :I g~vg~~
le\,<l oi htriri-
Acncv. rht u5e oi ih~. cni1~s1011~
trdding methr~d ha, Ird
'o
d~al~ropc~tliun;Ij
incrcasc,s
decreawb in emi,bions
in certain areas that cause or exacerbate emissions con-
centrations.
In the SO, example above, the issue would not be
whether the reductions mandated in the Acid Rain Pro-
"
The federal Clean Air Act of 1970 established the first Na-
tional Ambient Air Quality Standards, designed to protect
health and welfare, and required states to develop "state
implementation plans"
(SIPS) to achieve these standards. 42
U.S.C.
8
7401 et seq.
'"For SO,, for example, an unintended consequence of
these new ambient standards was the dispersion of SO,
through
tall stacks. The EPA permitted over a dozen states to
adopt
SIPS allowing sources to meet the new standard by
building tali stacks to disperse the SO, instead of reducing
emissions. This practice injected SO, into the higher atmo-
sphere where it remained longer, facilitating the chemical re-
actions that produce sulfuric acid and aggravating acid pre-
cipitation. See Vickie L.
Patton,
Re
New Air Quality Stan-
dards, Regional
Haze,
and Interstate Air Pollution Transpori,
28 ENVIL..
L. REP. 10,155 (1998).
'"
EPA,
NA~ONL
An
QvAUI?
AND
EMISSIONS
TRENDS
REPORT,
1999 EPA-454lE-01-004 (March 2001).
"
42 U.S.C. $7651 et seq. (imposing a 8.95 million ton cap
to be achieved by 2010).
IS
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Acio
RA~N
PKO-
GRAM: 2002 PROGRESS
REPORT at pp. 7-11, EPA-430-R-03-011
(NO-
"ember 2003). See also, U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency, Acio RAN PROGPUIM:
2001 PROGWSS
RLiiorr at pp. 35-37.
EPA-430-R-02-009 (November 2002).
"Congress has acted to advance several cap-and-trade
proposals for electric utilities, such
as the Clear Skies Act
(H.R. 999) introduced by Reps. Joe Barton @-Texas) and Billy
Tauzin
@.La.);
the Clean Power Act (S. 366) introduced by
Sen. Jim Jeffords @-Vt.): and the Clean Air Planning Act of
2003
(S. 843) introduced by Sens. Tom Carper (D-Del.), Lin-
coln Chafee
(R.R.I.), and Judd Gregg (3-N.H.). EPA an-
nounced the signing of proposed rules to reduce SO, emis-
sions in
a 28-state region to 2.7 million tons by 2015. U.S. EPA,
Air Quality Proposal to Deeply Cut
Power Plant Emissions is
Signed,
EPA Press Release
(Dec.
17, 2003; 34 ER 2742,
12il9i033.
gram were enough, but whether the program led to an
uneven allocation of the tons of reduction in a way that
exacerbated areas of concentration. such as the
Mid-
\vesr Ihe pwnr 1s >ln!ply char
\ye
mu>! diiierenri;fiic:
dn
3nalys1. ui rhe eifects oi regularol~ merhod rradlng-
trom rhe Ishue oi ,rrinjienc\, .~nd aa.3c.b~ !t.hcrht:r ~hc
method itself led to po1l;tant concentrations
6.
All Regulatory Systems Create Differentiated
Emissions Levels in
Plants
At similar levels of overall reductions, regionalor na-
tional source-soecific rate standards or
other remla-
,,
lions du nut mt:aningiully addrc% loc.~l emissions lev-
el, any
betrer rhan rr~dlng >).tern..
;\
plln(:lpal rchon
Is lhal rate-b:lsed re#ulatlon, dr~ ntrr cuntrul ihe o\,erall
amount of pollutio<, which depends on plant siting,
plant size, and utilization-whether a plant is operated
100 percent, 50 percent or
1 percent of the time. There-
fore rate systems do not guarantee per-plant reduc-
tions.
In addition, rate-based standards allow emissions
to increase due to economic growth, and so over time
may lead to greater overall emissions than cap-and-
trade systems.
allucste
For
manv
<$!,en
Plants.
number'
the cap-and-trade
oi ~llu\r,ance$
aDDroach.
. .
tr, rhe
which
pl.~nr.
may
be mure likely ru lead to cc~n~isrcnr
pc,llurant rc-
ductlunr than rhe rRre based appruach. kigure I >ho\r,
how rate-based systems can lead to greatly increased
pollution at the plant level with differences in plant uti-
lization, comparing a plant utilized at a 10 percent level
to one utilized at a 100 percent level. Although the al-
lowance allocation does not change, a rate-based regu-
latory system allows pollution emissions to increase
greatly as plant utilization increases.
Figure 1
r
-7
Plant Utilization Differences Chart:
How Rate-Based Systems Can Cause Hot Spots
I
I
Raie-based Emissions
C3
Allowances
120
I
L
10% Utilization
100% Utilization
.. J
I
A SNA
Giapbic/en425g01
C. Context of Existing Regulatory Standards
A further limitation of this study is that trading pro-
grams for
NOx and SO, exist simultaneously with other
regulatoly programs for criteria pollutants. Although
important, these standards would not be expected to
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT
"
2004
BY
THE
BUREAU
OF NAT IONAL AFFAIRS, INC., WASHINGTON. O.C.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
set on a case-bv-case hasi~.~'
These standards have
principally
affectkd new sources and have had relatively
little effect on compliance behavior of existing power
plants in the programs studied."'
D. NationaVRegional
-
vs.
Local Regulation
\
i~ri,~l
,.:i\.c.ii 13 1h.11 our srudy I3rgely concerns pro-
g,r.t!n, dc.,tgr.ed I<) ;,c.!i~c\e nartunal or rcg~oii~~l
level> oi
rcducttuns. :tnd i1<,1 local lcvel~. The chilice between
trading systems and rate-based standards is distinct
from a choice between national and local regulation.
Regardless of the type of regulation used to achieve na-
tional reductions, only local regulation can achieve lo-
cal pollution reductions over and above national stan-
dards.
--. . .
Our inquiry as to the method of regulation is however
relevant to hoth the national or local level, as trading
programs may be used to achieve these local goals as
well. For example in Houston, a local cap-and-trade
program was initiated in 2002 that will ultimately
achieve a 90 percent reduction in
NOx in the Houston-
Galveston area." Clearly, a national program aimed at
achieving a 50 percent reduction will only partially as-
sist Houston in this effort and added
local regulation is
needed. However, our study would he relevant to hoth
situations. in
clarifvine whether trading would he ex-
pected to iead to
e&is$ons concentrations within what-
ever area is defined as the area subject to regulation.
IV. Results of Trading Programs
This paper now examines the actual emission data
from four major emissions trading programs to deter-
mine whether thev resulted in shifts in emissions
;nnun< regiun, ot plrjnts I~LI Icd ru concenlr3rtng 10~31
enl!,,ivn-. .c\.elb \Ye ev~~ludre
iour rn:i]or progrdmh.
9
Phase I of the SO, Acid Rain Program (1995-1999);
I
Phase 11 of the SO, Acid Rain Program (2000 and
2001);
m
Ozone Transport Commission NOx Budget Program
(1999.2002); and
9
NOx Discrete Emission Reduction credit trading pro-
grams in several states.
"
New
Source Review establishes an emissions rate stan-
dard set by regulators on
a case-by-case basis based on the
specific
.. .
plant and power-generation
technology. 42 U.S.C.
!
..I.
,I
-
:\t,~r l',.',
,,<.,,
,,,urce sl:,!,,l>r<!>
1,,r SCl. c>.<~"I,~II>
re-
qt~.r~\
,cr-,khl~$?~
P~.L
;.,
C
P I<
:
ti,
I'h
:ind
~hc da::d:xr<ls
!n
I
,
2
A
4
,uprit, but
,,nI\.
'i:)
trntr,
~-
il~lhcr
\~~ ~
rh:in
ncs.
unl1.n
installed scrubbers from
197.
'8
to
~~
1994.
~ ~ ~ ,
when olants started to
install scrubbers for compliance with the Title IV cap-and-
trade
.......r
nromam.
~~"~~
I1.S.
- ~
ENEKGY
INFORMAXON
AGENCY,
PUB. NO. EIA-
0348(99)12.
Fi.ue
GAS DESULNRIIAIION
(TGD) C~ACITY
i~
OPSKA-
.T~ON AT
US. ELECTRIC
Unuri P~A~~Ts
e
OF
DECEMBER
1999, 2 Em.
Powin
ANNUAL.
table 30 (October 2000). This failure of existing
sources to reduce
poilGion promoted a series of lawsuits by
states and EPA in 1999 azainst a number of major utility com-
panies, only some of which have been settled.
"'The Mass Emissions Cap and Trade Program
(MECTP)
has been established by the Texas Commission an Environ-
mental Quality for certain stationary sources of nitrogen ox-
ides
(NOx) emissions in the Houston-Galveston nonattainment
area (HGA). The initial cap was implemented Jan. 1, 2002, with
mandatory reductions increasing over time until achieving the
final cap by Jan.
1, 2007. 30 Tex. Admin. Code
B
101.351. See
htt~:l~.emissionstradine.com/tx
facts.htm on the World
Wide Web
-
5704
COPYRIGHT
"
2004
BY THE BUREAU OF
V. SO, Acid Rain Program
The nation's largest emissions cap and allowance
trading program is the SO, cap-and-trade program un-
der Title
IV of the Clean Air
The program was de-
signed to reduce SO, emissions from electric utilities
by
10 million tons from 1980 levels. Its passage in 1990
broke a 10-year legislative impasse to address the pri-
mary cause of acid rain." The program combines an
SO, emissions cap set to reach 8.95 million tons by 2010
with a flexible implementation mechanism that lets
sources trade emissions allowances to achieve
eff-
ciencv
- ~
'l'hts
in
progratl~
reaching
h.b
.,
the
hecn
cap.
~n~plernc~nicd
iii
t\ro
phahcs
I'hasc I cunimencecl in 1!J!t5 and required rhc LI,:, I;jrg-
est, highest-emitting power units to make significant
initial emissions
reduction^.^" Starting in 2000, Phase
I1
requires all plants above 25 megawatts in capacity
(2,300 units in all) to comply with a nationwide emis-
sions cap set at 8.95 million tons of SO,." These reduc-
tion levels were achieved, although the opportunity for
banking allowances meant that many sources achieved
early reductions by emitting below their allocated levels
during Phase
I, and have used the stored allowances to
emit slightly above their allocated levels during the ini-
tial years of Phase
TI
(see Figure 2).
The Title
IV
program has been called one of the most
effective emissions reduction
Dromams,
. ..
principally he-
cauhe it achieves signit'icant and l~ern,nn>nt reducitc~n~
;it ven. lunr rompltance co\rs (.'<nnpli.lnce cohls lor lull
I'hit.,e II imr,lcmcnrnrion arc ehi~mared ar ,512 hill~un
per year, well below initial estimates that ranged from
$3 billion to
7
billion.38 The low cost is attributed to the
flexibility afforded by both the cap approach and trad-
ing mechanism. However, the program has achieved a
number of other notable results as well: virtually 100
percent compliance; high monitoring quality; low trans-
action cost to business; and very low administrative
costs to
gn~ernment.~~
A. Lack of Regional Emissions Shifts
Possibly the most important concern in the hot spot
debate has been whether trading programs would lead
to regional shifts in emissions. This concern was espe-
cially acute for the SO, Acid Rain Program, where it
"'This title was promulgated in the Clean
Air Act Amend-
ments of
1990,42 U.S.C.
$
7651 et seq. See generally A. Denny
Elleman et al., Mnm ion CLGW
AIR:
Tii~ U.S. ACID RNN PRO-
G-
(2000) and Byron Swift, Environmental Law Institute,
How Environmental Laws Work: An Analysis of the Utility
Sector's Response to Regulation
of
Nitrogen Oxides and Sul-
fur
Dioxide Under the Clean Air Act, 14 TGME ENVII. L.J. 309
(Summer 2001) [available at
hrrp:llwww.epa.govlairmarketsl
artic1eslindex.html an the Web]
3'
Richard Cohen, Wnskii~cior.
AT
WORK,
BACK ROOMS
;WD
Ci.w
Ain
(1990) (discussing congressional debates); Ian M.
Torrens et al.,
The
1990 Clean Air Act Amendments: Oven,iew,
Utility Industry Responses, and Strategic Implications, 17 ANN.
REV. Enrncu
& ENV'I
211, 213 (1992).
"
42 U.S.C.
$
7651~.
7
42
U.S.C.
$
7651d.
.'"
Ellerman, Denny, Lessons
from
Phase
2
Compliance
with the
US. Acid Rain Program, MIT CEEPR Working Paper
W-2003-009 at 4 (Cambridge, MA, May 2003) [see http:ll
mit.edulceeprIwwwlworkingpapers.htm
on the Web].
3s
See EPA, Acid Rain Program Compliance Reports 1995-
2002; references in note 34, supra; Brian Mclean, Evolution of
Marketable Permits: The
U.S. Experience with Sulfur Dioxide
Allowance Trading,
8 INT'L J. EMI.
&
POLL~ION
19 (1997).
ITIONAL AFFAIRS. INC.. WASHINGTON, O.C.
ER
ISSN
0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
-
Figure 2
Results of the SO2 Acid Rain Program (1995
-
2002)
!
............
[7
Allowances Allocated
C
Phase 1 Sources
..............
.................................................................
J
Source:
fPA,Acld Rain Pmgiam: Compliance RepoN
11995-20021:
and EPA,Acld
Rain
Program: hisslons Scorecard
11995-20021.
A BNA
Gmphiclen425g02
Bath
senes
are
aval!able
at
h~p://ww.epa.gov/aima~keii/em~s~~~~/~nde.html#le~oN
on the
Web.
was feared that trading could increase emissions from
and Northeast (14
states).*' The data show that during
Midwestern sources, whose emissions had traditionally
Phase 1, sources collectively emitted well below the
caused significant harm in sensitive
ecosvstems in the
baseline levels, as required by the cap, but also below
Northeastustates and Canada.4o This secgon examines
their allocation levels..
the data to see whether regional shifts have in fact
oc-
Note that there are two ways of determining the ef-
curred.
fect of the cap-and-trade program on shifts in emissions
levels. The most important is the comparison of
base-
1. Results of Phase I of the Acid Rain Program
Figure
3
shows the actual results from Phase I of the
Acid
Rain Program by region, for all units that partici-
pated in all five years of Phase
L4'
Three numbers are
illustrated for each region: the first
bar shows 1980
baseline emissions levels;4z the second, the allowances
allocated on an annualized basis; and the last, actual
emissions on an annualized basis. The regions are com-
posed of the Midwest
(8 states), Southeast (8 states),
40Acid precipitation damage has been most pronounced in
the northern tier and northeastern United States and Canada
because the forests and lakes in these areas
are more sensitive
......., .................
........
sation units. that ~artici~ated
in all
ti\
ie
vears of Phase I htle
N allowed hrms'to select wh~ch olants would uartlcmate ~n
Phase I as substitution units each'yzar, and so ihe daia does
not include emissions
for those substitution units that partici-
pated in fewer than
5 years.
'"
The intent of Congress in creating Title
IV
was to effect a
l0-million-ton reduction in SO, from 1980 levels. However,
scaled to equal
1980 emissions.
line emissions levels (the left bar) with actual emissions
levels during the program (the right
bar). This incorpo-
rates
both elements of a cap-and-trade program-the
reductions caused by the cap itself and any changes
caused by the trading program. A second view of only
the effect of trading would compare the allowance allo-
cation (the middle bar) with actual emissions. However,
it is important to view cap-and-trade systems as a com-
plete system, as the imposition of the cap also strongly
affects emissions results.
a. Greatest Reduction
In
the Midwest.
The nlosr ilnpor-
rant iinding in rhh I'hasc I dara is cxrrernely good
nev.r
by far the-greatest reductions from baseline emissions
in
terns of both tonnage and percentage reductions
took place in the Midwest, the region with the highest
emissions. Midwestern sources reduced SO, emissions
by
55
percent from baseline levels, compared to only 45
percent in other regions (see Figure 4).
Two factors may help to explain this result.
The first
is that the formula for allocating allowances was itself a
13
The Midwestern states are Illinois, Ohio, Indiana, Iowa,
Michigan, Minnesota, Missouri, and Wisconsin; the
Southeast-
em states are Alabama, Kentuce, Georgia, Florida, Missis-
sippi, North Carolina, South Carolina and Tennessee: and the
Northeastern states are Connecticut, the District of Columbia,
Delaware, Maine,
Maiyland, Massachusetts, New Hampshire,
New Jersey, New
Yark, Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, Vermont,
Virginia, and West Virginia. All sources participating in Phase
I are covered within these regions except for one unit in Kan-
sas.
ENVIRONMENT
REPORTER
ISSN 0013-9211
BNA
5-7.04
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Figure 3
Figure
4
I---
Baseline Emissions, With Phase I Allocations
and Emissions of
SO2 by Reglon
1
SO2
(tons)
;
3
Phase I Ailowances Annuaiized
.....
i
U
Phase I Emissions Annualized
.
,
i
Midwest
Southeast
Northeast
i
hnp://&.epa.gov/airmahea/emisionsl
indexhtmiiiiepoits on
the
Web.
factor in reducing emissions concentrations proportion-
ately greater in high emissions areas such as the Mid-
west.
In Phase 1, allowances were allocated to units on
the
basis of 2.5 lh. SO, per million Btu (mmBtu) multi-
plied by their 1980 baseline utilization. This meant that
the dirtier olants with hieh baseline emissions rates had
10 reducc emi,siuns signiiic~lnrly more ro rexch thclr ai-
Io\\.,tncc :ilic,c.ttiun rhan cleaner source$ dld 'She nlloc;l-
tion method disproportionately affected sources burn-
ing the high-sulfur coals in the Midwest, leading to
greater incentives to reduce emissions in this region.
The second reason is that large plants reduced emis-
sions the
most,44 which also led to greater reductions in
the Midwest, as that region has relatively more large
plants. The result is that by far the greatest reduction
occurred in the region
with the greatest emissions,
thereby contributing to cooling rather than creating hot
spots.
b.
Consistency Among Regions
in
the
Use of
Trading. The
second evident feature of the Phase 1 data is that the
three major regions are quite similar in
terms of the use
of trading mechanisms: sources in each region reduced
emissions by a roughly similar percent below alloca-
tions and banked most of these saved
allowance^.^^
Since emissions in each region were consistently be-
low the total amount allocated, there is also little to no
44
See Part N.B infra.
45
Banking refers to emitting below allowance allocations in
order to save allowances to use in future
yean.
As
shown,
mast firms in Phase I chose to bank allowances to use in Phase
11, when they would face a much lower emissions cap. In all,
nearly
three-quatiers of the allowances freed up for emissions
trading in the
fint three years of Phase I were banked for later
use. Ellerman 2000 at Section 6.6. Although the banked allow-
ances
are expected to he used in the future, banking causes
early reductions, which has positive environmental conse-
quences in reducing sulfur deposition earlier.
Title IV Phase I Emissions Reductions
From
1980 Baseline*
Region
From Baseline
Midwest
3,079,034
-55%
Southeast
'
1,168,720
-46%
Northeast
1
854,173
1
-43%
Total
5,101,927
-50%
...
--
~-
'Unia panicipatinr ail
five
yean only.
A
8NA @aphic/en425@4
discernible effect regarding the spatial shift of emis-
sions due to
tradinz. The oniv thine that can be said is
rhnr sources in the Sourhensi banked siighriy more AI-
lo\vnncc, Than t,rher rcg10115 (35 percenr,
II
oppu,cd
lo
LLJ
r)ercerlr in the So~nheasr ;ind
2:i
Dcn't.nt in
ihc
\lid-
west). A contributing factor to this result was the
"BUBA" strategy of the major utility in the region, the
Southern Company, to "Bank, Use and Buy
Allow-
ances:" the comoanv banked almost 2 million tons of al-
lowances
4~o&ev~r,
an examinat~on of the Phase I1
results shows that the extra allowances banked
m the
Southeast were not traded to other
reeions. but orima-
rily were used to allow sources in the Southeast to emit
slightly above their allowance allocations in Phase
11.
2. Results of Phase ll of the Acid Rain Program
Phase 11 of the Acid Rain Program commenced in
2000 and covers all 2,300 units above 25
IMW, not just
the "big dirty" plants included in Phase I.
In Phase 11,
allowance allocations were lowered to reach the final
cap level of 8.95 million
tons.47 Figure 5 shows the re-
sults for 2001, the second year of implementation of
Phase
II.*'The regions comprise the Midwest (8 states),
Southeast (10 states), Northeast (14 states), and West
(17
state^).'^ Note that sources are emitting slightly
46
See Gary R. Hart, Southern Company's BUBA Strategy
in
the
SO, Allowance Market, in
Eu~ss~ovs
Tioioi~c 204, 205 @i-
chard F. Kosobud ed., 2000);
see
generally, Swift, 2001 at 335
and
--~~~
Fie.
- ~- -
2-5
-.
''
42 U.S.C.
9
7651d.
4R
2001 was selected because it is the intermediate year of
implementation of Phase
11 (all three years of which are very
similar in their emissions characteristics), and also lacked the
400,000 bonus allowances allocated in 2000.
**The Midwestem states
are
Illinois, Ohio, Indiana, lowa,
Michigan, Minnesota, Missouri, and Wisconsin: the
Southeast-
em states are Alabama, Arkansas, Kentucky, Georgia, Florida,
Louisiana, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, and
Tennessee; the Northeastern states are Connecticut, the
Dls-
trict of Columbia, Delaware, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts,
New Hampshire, New Jersey, New
York, Pennsylvania, Rhode
Island, Vermont, Virginia, and West Virginia; and the Western
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT
a
2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NAT IONAL AFFAIRS, INC.. WASHINGTON, D.C.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
above their allocation levels as they use up the hank of
greater emissions in Phase
I1
in the Southeast therefore
allowances saved through early reductions in Phase I.
reflect banking behavior by these same sources, and not
Figure 5
.......
.......
......
....
........
-7
Baseline Inventory,Allocations, and Emissions of SO2 by Region in 2001 (Phase 11)
I
I
West
Midwest
Again, the news for hot spots is very good. In Phase
11,
as in Phase I, by far the greatest reductions occurred
in
the Midwest, the most polluted region, and all three
major regions-Midwest,
Southeast, and
Northeast-
behaved similarly in the use of trading.
Note that the relatively few plants in the West be-
haved quite differently from eastern plants. Western
plants tend to he newer and cleaner than Eastern
plants, with ready access to low-sulfur Powder River
Basin coal, and so had low baseline emissions levels.
As
a consequence, the allowance allocation to Western
plants was actually above their baseline emission levels.
Their actual emissions in 2001 were slightly below their
allocation level, but above their baseline
level.50
a. Consistency Among Regions in Use of Trading.
The
first major point with regard to hot spots is that all three
major regions achieved similar results in the use of
trading mechanisms, if one compares the level of 2001
allowance allocations with the level of 2001 emissions.
However, because sources are using up the hank of al-
lowances accumulated by early reductions made in
Phase
I, sources in each of these regions emitted
slightly over their allocated level in 2001 (although well
below their baseline emissions level).
Again, the only slight difference in regions is in the
Southeast, where sources bad slightly more emissions
in Phase
.
11
~~
in
~~
com~arison
~
to their allocation level than
thr orncr rep~lrlj lio\ve\.el-. rhi I> s~mply rhe r~~n\.crse
(,!
their bctid\!ur in
Pli.~~c
1.
lien S~ulhcast
bouwes
had the greatest amount of early reductions (see Figure
3).
The slightly greater reduction in Phase I and slightly
states are all those west of and including the Great Plains,
ex-
cept Texas.
"O
Since the allocation methodology assigned plants allow-
ances based on baseline emissions
of 1.2 lb SO, per million Btu
(mmBtu),
very
low-emitting plants such as many in the West
received more allowances than baseline emissions, leading to
the emissions characteristics
shown in Figure 5.
Southeast
Northeast
j
....
-.
...
..
2002);
A
BNA GaphicJen425gOS
any spatial flow of allowances to or from other regions.
b.
Significantly Greater Total Reductions Occurred in the
Midwest.
The second point relevant to hot spots is very
significant: if one looks at the environmental result, in
comparing 1980 baseline levels with 2001 emissions,
considerably greater reductions occurred in the Mid-
west than in other regions. Sources in the eight-state
Midwest region achieved a
55 percent reduction from
baseline levels and contributed
60 percent of the total
tons of abatement, far exceeding other regions, as
shown in Figure
6.
The reasons for the greater reductions in the Midwest
appear to be the same as in Phase
I. A significant cause
is that disproportionately large emissions reductions
are made at the largest plants, as described in part B
he-
low. Many Midwestern plants are among the dirtiest
sources (those with the highest baseline emissions),
in-
cludins 10 out of the highest 17 olants and 15 out of the
next
3-1
higlicsr planls. 'lh15 over-re)~resenlnti~~~~
ui Iilrgr.
plant, accounts ior
17
percent oi the grearcr rhan a\,cr-
age reductions in the Midwest."'
"
The discussion in subpart B shows that higher-polluiing
plants tend lo reduce emissions more than others in the SO,
trading program, which would help to explain the greater
ie-
ductions in the Midwest, as many Midwestern plants are over-
represented in the third and fourth
quartiles, the plants with
the highest baseline emissions shown in Figure 9.
A detailed
analysis shows that Midwestern plants constitute
42 percent of
total baseline emissions, but constitute 59 percent of the larg-
est plants in the fourth quartile
(10 out of the 17 largest plants,
representing 2,574,681 out of the 4,394,151 tons of 1980 base-
line emissions in this quartile), and 44 percent
of the third
quartile (15 of the
next largest 34 plants, representing
1,911,019 out of 4,359,691 tons of 1980 baseline emissions in
the next quartile); however Midwestern plants are under-
represented in the
smalier plants, making up only
37
percent
of
the third quartile and 29 percent of the quartile with the low-
est emitters. if Midwestern sources were to have behaved
ac-
cording to the national average, their baseline emissions of
ENVIRONMENT REPORTER
ISSN
00139211
BNA
5704
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
-
Figure 6
--
Figure 7
.............
Phase II SO2 Emissions Reductions From
I
Baseline Levels, by Region in 2001
1
Region
IotalTons
Reduced
Percent
From
Baseline
Change
West (17 states)
1
(+239,430)
123%
Midwest
(8
states)
1
4,046,904
-55%
Southeast
(
10 states)
1,466,343
1
30%
Northeast (13 states)
1,404,920
1
37%
A second factor is that Title
IV's allowance allocation
method disproportionately reduced allowance alloca-
tions to the dirtiest sources-shown
by the difference
between baseline emissions and allocation levels in Fig-
ure
5. Both of these factors indicate that the larae re-
duction made in the Midwest is not a
coincidence,-but a
predictable aspect of the SO2 allowance trading pro-
gram.
C. Reductions Even Greater in an Expanded Midwest Re-
gion.
The finding of a disproportionately large amount
of emissions reduction in the Midwest is reinforced if
one slightly expands the Midwest to include
Kentuce,
Tennessee, and West Virginia. These states behaved
quite similarly to Midwestern ones and altogether
achieved a
54 percent reduction-compared to only a 16
percent reduction in the rest of the United States. To-
gether, the 11 states in this expanded Midwest region
constitute 60 percent of baseline emissions, but
contnh-
uted a very high
80
percent of all tons of abatement
from
1980 emissions levels. Again, this is extremely
good news for hot spots-a disproportionately high por-
tion of reductions came
fmm the most polluted region
(see Figure
7).
d. Counterfactual Emissions Also Show Greater Midwest-
ern Reductions.
In the above analysis, we compare ac-
tual Phase
I1 emissions with baseline emissions to de-
termine the contribution of Midwestern sources. We
note that a similar conclusion is reached if one com-
pares baseline emissions to an estimate of the
"counter-
factual emissions" that would have occurred in 2001
without Title
N.
The Center for Energy and Environ-
mental Policy Research of the Massachusetts Institute
of Technology (MIT) calculated such counterfactual
emissions and determined that the great majority,
77
7,326,537 tons should have been reduced by only 44 percent to
4.1 million tons; this over-representation among large sources
alone would predict that Midwest sources should reduce emis-
sions
tr~ approximately 3.7 million tons. Actually, Midwestern
sources emitted 3.28 million tans in 2001, so the over-
representation of large sources explains almost half (47 per-
cent) of this difference
behveen predicted (4.1 million) and ac-
tual (3.28 million) emissions. The lower allowance allocation
likely also played
a causative role.
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT @ 2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NF
1
to
Cornoaring
tl;e ~e;
Exnanded
of'the United
Midwest
States:
Region
-
dase
inr
[PI
$suns 2071
A ohdnces
apa 2001 En
n
bns
(all Phase II Plants)
.....
C
2001 Emissions
I
Expanded Midwest
Rest of the U.S.
percent, of abatement has been achieved at the older,
high-emitting plants located in Midwestern
states.52
We conclude therefore that the Phase I1 cap-and-
trade program led to emissions reduction exactly where
they are needed most to address health and environ-
mental
vroblems-in
the Midwest-where
sources
achle\.cd three rime, rhe reduct~ons from I!liu h:<rclin~
n~ns
1 SOUICES in the rest (,t the cuuntl?
B. Analysis of Plant-Level Emissions
A d~iicrenr
wn!
ru e\ralu:~rc rhe ell\.ironrncnial concc-
qucnc:~:s oi a cap-and-rrilde ippro.icli is ti, :~rst.s \vhc.rc
emissions reductions have taken place on a plant level.
acrlh.
Did
can-and-trade
pli~nts, or
\\,on:
oroaams
. -
there
reduce
disprupvrri<,n.ile
emissions evenlv
recluc-
:luns in plan13 \r.~th reldr~\.ely high or Iou, emi,s~rrna le\
el>'? Ileducr~ons ar higher-emirt~ng pl.111ti wuuld hs\c
n
beneficial tendency to cool, and
create, hot spots.
The results from all the examined trading programs
show strongly that disproportionately greater reduc-
tions
lf,\,el bnal\,,ir
were made
rhc,reior~!
at the
shoa.,
hieher-emittine
rhd trading
~,
~lants.
.
[)rogr.irn>
A olant-
re-
iulr in rhe d~,pcr\~un,
nor the ',oncenrr:rriun id C:III,-
sions.
Figures
8 and 9 show emission data by size of the
source (unit or plant) for Phases I and I1 of the Acid
Rain Program. Sources are grouped into four quartiles
according
...
to
~lant size. with each auartile renresentine
zourccs wnh 25 percent
01
hawline ernlbslr,ns. 'lhc
ic~unh quan~lc on the I-~ghr hide reprcscnr3 II ie\v i.trpr-
(hlphest-cm~rrinyr s,,urres. \rhel-c,a, thc i~rd qilartilc ,,n
the far left represents a large number -of small
"
Elleman, Denny,
Lessons
from
Phase
11
Compliance
with the Acid Rain
Program at 4. MET CEEPR Working Paper
2003-009
(Cambridge, MA 2003) [available at http:jj
web.rnit.edulceepr~l2003-009.pdf on the Web].
iTlONAL AFFAIRS. iNC., WASHINGTON. DC.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Figure
8
-.
..
.
....
.......... .~
~.
.
r
I
1
!
Phase I SO2 Allowance Allocations and Emissions
by
Unit Size
(by
Quartiles)*
1
1980 Emissions
C
Phase I Allowances Annualized
C
Phase I Emissions Annualized
3,000,000
-..
....
i
_1
i
1st
Quartile
2nd Quartile
3rd
Quartile
4th
Quartile
.....
..
.-.........
............
4
'This table war aoned by units based on the
amount
ai their basline emissions; with each quanile iepiesentingsoiirces iesponsible far
A
BNA
Graphlc/en425%08
appmnimateiy 2.5 miliion tons of
SO2
in
1980me
24 units (at approximately
11
plants) with the iaigest baseline
emisions
comprise
the
'Izige
dim"
units
in theiouith quanile; the next iaigest 42
mils
campke the third quaniie; there
are
69
"nib in the third quamie: and the
remziping 235
units
are in the founh quaitile repiesenting the units with the smallest baseline emissions level.
Source:
WA,ACid
Rain
Piogmm: Campiiance Repons
11995-19991:
and
EPA.Acld Rain Program: Emissions Scoiecad
11995-19991.
Both sen= are
avaiabie
at hdp://w.epa.gou/atmaiRets/em~~~ian~/~nde~~htmi#iep~on
tkiYeb
Figure 9
-
Phase II SO2 Allowance Allocations and Emissions
by
Plant Size
(by
Quartiles)
1
1980 Emissions
Ci
2001 Allowances
J
2001
Emissions
5,000,000
-.
I-
I
1st Quartile
2nd Quartile
3rd Quartile
4th
Quartile
I
.. ..................
A
BNA
Giaph1c/eo425@9
'
sources.53 The data reveals that the larger sources
achieved significantly greater emissions reductions in
both Phase
I and
11,
and especially in Phase
11.
53
We choose to sort by size of baseline emissions (as op-
posed to another factor such as capacity) because the most sig-
nificant environmental goal is the total reduction of pollution
the fourth
quartile, the next largest in terms of their baseline
from baseline emissions to present emissions. The quartiles
emissions make
u~
the third quartile, and many sources with
sort sources by sire into four groups with roughly equivalent
relatively low baseline emissions levels comprise the first quar-
sources
total hareline
(with
........................
emissions.
the highest
such
baseline
that the
emissions
reiativeiv
~~ ~
~"
levels)
"large
-
make
dim"
;p
tile.
at the
This
few
allows
"large
us
dirty.'
to determine
source
whether
in the fourth
reductions
qua&,
are
or
made
the
ENVIRONMENT REPORTER
ISSN 00139211
BNA
5-7-04
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Figure 10
Results of the OTC NOI: Cap-and-Trade Program (1999-2002)
Ll"","""
,
......
--x;-i,;;;";;A,C,,
1
;---- --- - 1
.............
..................
r;i
Emissions
t
~
i
~
'
I
I
..
...........
.......
---
.........
-
- -
"
-
6
:::
1:.
...
:.:
3
2
..,-
- -
5.
.'.'
1990 Baseline 1995
.......
kt.
I.. I
......
I 1-1
Emissions
[Post-RACn
1999
Source:
EPA,
OTC
NOx Budget Program Cornpilance Repom
11999
-
20023;
availableat http://w
For Phase I, Figure 8 shows that the largest units in
the fourth quartile reduced emissions the most, by 67
percent
below 1980 baseline levels, compared to 59 per-
cent for the third quartile, 35 percent for the second,
and 40 percent for the fourth quartile containing the
smallest sources.
I'he lind~ng
(31 d~cprop<~~?~oni~teIy
gre:lrcr reducrluns
iruln tli~ lirge>l wurres
I
even more ,lrik~ng in IJh;lse
I
.
I
i I
!
I he dara shu\v 1h3r \IEIIIII-
cantlv exeater redGctions have been achieved as aver-
baseline levels, compared to a 48
peicent>eduction by
the next 34 plants in the second quartile, 41 percent
from 71 plants in the third, and only 10 percent from the
remaining 887 smallest
These data confirm a general prediction about
cap-
and-trade programs, which is that they will tend to cre-
ate incentives for the dirtiest plants to clean up the
most. where the economies of scale are the
createst.
2000
2001
I
2002
2003 OTC Budget
.............
-
i.epa.gov/a~rmaiueW~mpmt/~nde~~htn!
on
the
Web.
A
BNR Giaphlc/en425glO
program to reduce NOx emissions from electricity gen-
erators and industrial sources during the summer
ozone season." Phase
I commenced in 1994 and im-
posed
rtlrc-b:~sed 5land;lrd. h1rn11:ir ro rhc SOX ralc
srnnd:irds iniportd under 'l'lrle I\'
'
I'hsic II <I! I~L.
prc,-
gram imposed a seasonal emissions cap and allowance
trading program for
NOx to achieve additional reduc-
tions, which covered nine of the 12 stares from 1999 to
2002. In 2003, Phase
I11 reduced the emissions cap level
further, as the OTC program becomes part of a
larfer
NOx "SIP call" trading program for Eastern states.'
Althoueh the OTC budget
.....
Droeram is a ca~-and-trade
progr:irn alrnildr ru rhc 'l'11Ie I\' SO. prugr:,m, Ir has
;i
number ~,f d~fierenr itarurc>. 11iaredd oi aIloc?i!~ng :,I-
lowances to each source, it allocated allowances to each
state in accordance with that state's share of the re-
gional budget. The states in-turn allocated the allow-
ances to sources within the state. Another feature was
that the OTC states established an Inner, Outer, and
Northern zone for the purpose of setting reduction tar-
-.
eets. but because tradine
~~
was allowed on a 1:l basis be-
('JIJII:~~ inve~IIncnl In lhc iorl~i oi pruceis cqulprncnl or
rwecn all zuncs, roughly rquivall-nr eniission, reduc-
cuilrtoi equlpnienl, urh
ar
scrubber<. \vould bc pre-
rlons were achic\.ed in ;ill 7one
'^
,\lrhough bunk~ng is
cl~cleu 1<, l~c- ~iixde dl lilrxc plants \vhcrc the niclsl rcdur-
~lluwed.
;I mech;in~sm r;~llcd rlun. conrl.ol ~orcnr~dllv
r~.-
tions can be achieve forthe investment, and where the
per-ton cost of reductions will be cheapest. The actual
evidence confirms this theory, and shows convincingly
that, if anything, trading may be expected to cool hot
spots and not create them.
VI. OTC NOx
Budget
-
Program
-
I hc ,ec<rnd major
I'S
c.1~-:lnd-lrdde program har
1)ei.n ~nil)lunic:n:ed I)? rhe
Ozcsnr.
'l'ran,pc~ti Cumrnli-
bun.
.I
co.111tiun ui 12 Sonhc.;~srcrn >tares with u un~ficd
oroeressivelv larger number of smaller sources in the follow-
Inglquartilei
"
Note that the
-
analysis for Phase I is for units, and that for
Phase
I1 is for plants (which may contain several units), al-
though the Rndings are expected to be similar in either case.
Since Phase
11
has many more sources, we show data at the
plant level,
as we find the most environmentally relevant con-
cern is the level of emissions at the site or plant level.
duces the amount of banked allowances that
cat; be
used in future
years.59
''
See Memorandum of Understanding Among the States of
the Ozone Transport Commission on Development of a Re-
gional Strategy Concerning the Control of Stationary Source
Nitrogen Oxide Emissions
(Sept. 27, 1994), available at http:/i
www.otcair.org on the Web.
56
In Phase I of the OTC program, states required sources
to install Reasonably Available Control Technology
(RACT)
by
1994, a standard roughly equivalent to the Title
N NOx stan-
dards based on
low-NOx burner technolow. 42 U.S.C.
B
7651f.
otcreport.pdf on the Web.
56
111
. -. -
at
.
7
. ,
''
See generally EPA, OTC NOn
BUDGET
PROGRAM:
2002
COM-
PUN~CF
REPORT 2 (20031, available at htrp://wu?.epa.gov/
aimaiketsicmprpt/otc02/inde~.htrnl an the Web.
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT
a
2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS, INC., WASHINGTON. D.C.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Te-11 -.....
~-.
I
Allowances Allocated and Emissions of NOx Under
~ -.. . ..
OTC Program
~-- . . .. .. .....
7
..
...
1
1
1999
-
2002 Allocations Annualized
'
tZ
1999
-
2002 Emissions Annualized
Maryland
Delaware
Pennsylvania
New Jersey
& D.C.'
'Note that most Mawland and
DC
wuns dld not paiticipate in the program untll2001, and ai
2002,due ioa law suitmedata
in
thetzbleshow
only
2002 aiiocationsand emissions.
Source:
Em
OrC Budget Pmgram Cornpilalee Repom;
(Mawland
data for2002
only).
The OTC NOx cap-and-trade program, which re-
duced emissions by 60 percent from
1990 baseline lev-
els, and by
35 percent from estimated RACT levels
achieved under Phase
I."'
Surprisingly, sources have
lowered overall emissions by more than the allowance
allocation in each of the four ozone seasons
(1999-
2002).
crnl,>,<,lis
.
as
~
shown
were belt,\\.
in Fimre
-
allo\tanc~,
10. Also.
a~lucariun
as discussed
level:.
below.
In all
,laits hur \lx?land. \vhosr enrn intu the program
\\'3,
J~~1:tvcii
due to a lau,iuit ;\I%). .~lial\.>~'s
by
El':\
and In-
dependent researchers show
that the cap-and-trade
program has been effective in reducing both average
and peak emissions levels by a similar proportion, alle-
viating a concern that the OTC program might not re-
duce short-term peak
NOx emissions."'
We examine the emissions data to
determine the ef-
fect of trading on emissions concentrations in two dif-
ferent ways. First, we look at the data by state to deter-
mine if shifts in emissions occurred
reeionallv,
..
and then
b\ Inner ,find Ou!tr zonc to ~ee
ti rhcrc mere :In) C3\1-
rc,-\rc.l emls,lc,rt, ihllr.
.I5
wilh rhe
SO,
pmgrani, rile
d.iti
.t.,,>v
\.c:n.
l~rtle reglotidl ,hiirtng ui cmi\sti~ns.
A. Analysis of Emissions Shifting by State
Viewed on a state-by-state basis, very little emissions
shiftina
. .
can be observed, as emissions reductions in
mmr
.!Ate, rh;ic.c:.~l:! the large unes. \\.ere quite c(rn-
>t,rent .~\ei.:lg~ng
11 pcricnr belt,\\. rhe~r .tllo~.nrcd IL.\.-
I
Il(,~ve\.er. ~ligliriy grc.iter rh:jn 3\.er.~gf. enihrioi~>
"'
EPA, NOx
BUDGET
PRUGWM:
1999-2002 PROGRESS
REPORT
at
6-7 (2003). Sources received allowance allocations represent-
ing either
a 55 percent or 65 percent reduction fmm 1990 base-
line levels, depending on whether they were located in the
Outer or lnner
zones, In addition, 24,635 bonus allowances
were provided, which slightly increased allocations.
"'
Id. at 8. See also Farrell, Alexander E., Temporal
Hotspots in Emissions Trading Programs: Evidence from the
Ozone Transport Commission
NOx Budget. Presented at an
EPA conference, Market Mechanisms and Incentives: Applica-
tions to Environmental Policy
(Washington, D.C., May 1-2,
2003).
-
ENVIRONMENT REPORTER
ISSN 00139211
New York
Connecticut
Rhode Island Masschusetts
New
Hampshire
I source$ did not hI!y panicipate until
h
BNh
Graphic/en425gll
reductions occurred in New England (due in part to an
unplanned outage of a New Hampshire unit) and
slightly less than average in Maryland. The result in
Maryland, however, was affected
by a lawsuit that de-
layed the entry
of most sources, which created uncer-
tainty and may have allowed sources to take advantage
of the
lower-than-expected price of allowances. This
situation. thoueh anomalous. created a small emissions
matically neutral
north-to-south direction, and so
should not affect transport or hot spots (see Figure
11)
B. Viewing Emissions by lnner and Outer Zones
Another way to judge whether spatial emission shifts
occurred under the OTC
NOx program is to view
whether there were
"wrong-way" shifts in emissions
that moved emissions upwind, or in an east-to-west di-
rection. This can he readily determined because the
OTC program was divided into an Inner Zone compris-
ing the heavily populated
conidor from Washington,
D.C., to Boston, almost all of which is classified as an
ozone
nonattainment area, and a more westerly Outer
Zone."
62
DUB to the lawsuit, Maryland sources did not participate
fully in the program until 200'2, when they emitted 6,290 tons
over their allocation level.
In contrast, sources in New England
emitted an average of 9,000 tons below their allocated levels.
Data
froni EPA, 2002 NOx Budget Program Cofnpiianm
Re-
port st
2
(June 25,2003). Therefore, if one compares the lower
emissions in New England
and the higher emissions in Mary-
land to the average emissions rate achieved in all states, the
re-
sult is that 7,500 tons of emissions were "shifted" annually
from New England states to
Maiyland due to the flexibility ai-
lowed by trading. Note however that a portion of these net re-
ductions will never be emitted, due to flow control that reduces
the value of banked tons.
CJSee Ozone Transport Commission, NOx Budget Pro-
gram: 1999-2002 Progress Report at 5 (EPA, Washington, D.C.,
2003)
[available at
http:/hYu?u.epa.gov/ainnarkets/otc/
BNA
5-7-04
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
The data show that from implementation of the pro-
gram resulted in
comparable reductions in both
zones-a 59 oercent reduction in the Outer Zone and a
.)h
~>~.r~enr
reduct1111> in rhc! Iilrier Zone (hec Figure 12)
"'
Alrhough rht ruduction le\.els \verc. alinost idc!niical
to the extent there was a one-percent shift in emissions,
in terms of wind direction it was a
"rieht-wav"
.,
shift in
cniis,itmb iron1 \\e,rern to ea,rcrn ,ources, reducing
!r:~nsp~Jn
of ZOx
:I
cl~ntrel-\
15 1ha1 reductlun~ in
nonanainment areas are 1 percent less than reduction
in more westerly attainment areas, which is not desir-
able. Either way, the shift in emissions was slight,
showing again that trading programs have achieved
consistency in emissions results.
C. Daily Emissions Levels
An even more unusual findine
.,
concerns the lack of
~,.rri,~c,r(il
shiii~ng
ui
emiiiion.,, even on a dally ba4 in
rke
0
I
(: ?Ox
c;ip-and-rradc program l'hc rejiuldiiun <rt
NOx presents a problem for any regulatory system he-
cause NOx formation is episodic and occurs principally
on hot summer days. More power is also generated on
hot days due to increased demand, potentially causing
the most pollution on precisely the worst days. How-
ever, it is hard to regulate daily pollutant releases, ei-
ther through a cap-and-trade program that caps total
seasonal tons, or via rate standards, which allow more
pollution to occur whenever generation increases.
Notwithstandinn these issues. the
NOx cau-and-trade
program resulted-in lowering tons of NO; emissions
both in total and on high.-emissions days. Both average
and peak emissions during the ozone season declined
by roughly the same amount after imposition of the
Phase
I1 cap."" EPA noted that this finding "shows that
the seasonal budget is reducing daily emissions, even
on the days with the highest
emis~ions."~~his
finding
\ugge\t\ -that c:ap-~nd:rr,ldt. programs ;are po55ihl\.
niorc eiiecriv~ rli~tl rate-h:lst.d srandards in c~,nsisrcrirly
rediaclng crnrh~io!i, rcg:irdiea5
-hen-tenn changes.
VII. Discrete Emission Reduction Credit Trading
-
I hc (,idr.,r lurm ur enn\\iuns trsdirlg ii credil trading
prour:jm,. I:I'.\ hs, ill10\l'ed mlirkct-intt>nri\.u pollcle,.
incLding open-market emissions or credit trading pro-
erams. to be used for criteria ~ollutants"~
under the
Clean .\IT :\<.I in order r,, reduce the corr5 oi compliilnce
\vl!lluur 5:icrlitcing ;ill. quality
"'
Ofi~et prnl(r:lni\ \r,erc
h
d I I! and discrere emi,sion rcductiunh
otcreport.pdf on the Web]; there was also a Northern Zone, but
this had little relevance during Phase
11, as Maine and Vermont
did not
DarticiDate, and New York and New HamDshire in-
cluded their
nkhern
areas
in the Phase I1 program..
""
Note that equivalent emissions reductions were made in
both zones despite differing allocation
of allowances. Sources
L",
67
Criteria pollutants are carbon monoxide, lead, NOx, SO,,
volatile organic compounds, and particulate matter.
6R
EPA has established midelines for the use of such pro-
Figure 12
i
Comparison of Outer and lnner Zone
NOx Emissions From 1990 to 2002
I
1
1990 Baseline
C
2002AllowancesAllocated
! !
I
Outer Zone
Inner Zone
.......
A
Source:
EPA.
NOx Budget Piagiam:
A BNA GiaphIclen425g12
1999
-
2002 Progress Report (2W3)
PER) credit tradingprograms have been adopted in six
states since 1995. DER programs provide flexibility for
sources complying with federal emissions standards
that do not involve new sources or hazardous pollutants
(such as "reasonably achievable control
technology" or
RACT
state emissions
standards)
standards.
and with sources comnlvinn
." -
with
These "open-market" systems are established
through a certification process in which sources
cany
out specific projects to create emissions reductions, and
then obtain regulatory approval of the tons of reduc-
tions created, which can then be traded in the
form of
quently
emission
used,
credits.
the DER
Althoueh
credit
"
trading
offset
.
oroerams
promams
-
have
are
fre-
re-
siltedin relatively few trades, due in p& to the trans-
action costs involved and regulatory
un~ertainty.'~
A. Largest Plants Reduced the Most
A review of the results of six state DER programs and
the state procedures involved was recently published by
Incentive Rules: 59 Fed. Reg. 16,690 (April 7, 1994); U.S. Envi-
ronmental
Protection Agency, Proposed Model Open Market
Trading Rule for Ozone Smog Precursors, 60 Fed. Reg. 39,668
(Aug. 3, 1995); EPA, Emissions Trading Policy Statement, 51
Fed. Reg. 43,814
@ec. 4, 1986) (pt. I).
"'These programs are reviewed in Environmental Law in-
stitute, Emission Reduction Credit Trading Systems: An Over-
view
of
Recent Results and an Assessment
of
Best Practices.
Environmental Law Institute (October
2002), available at
http:l~.elistore.org/reportsSdetail.asp?1D=10694
on the
Web. In general, open market credit trading programs have
not generated significant trading opportunities
or cost reduc-
tions. See generally, Dudek, Daniel
&
John Palmisano, Emis-
sions
Trading: Why Is
This
TnorougkbredHobbied?, 13 Colum.
J. Envtl. L. 217 (1988); Hahn, Robert
&
Gordon Hester, Where
Did All the Markets Go? An Analysis
of
EPA's Emissions Trad-
ing Program, 6 Yale J. on Reg. 109 (1989).
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT" 2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NP \TIONAL AFFAIRS, INC.. WASHINGTON, D.C.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
New Jersey B Generation and Use of NOx DERs by
I
County Ozone Attainment Status (1992-2000)
Generated
(99%)
1
(1%)
1
Used
I
172%)
1,056
I
(28%)
403
1
O
I
I
Severe
NOx
emission;
ddta.
Moderate
Marginal
the Environmental Law ~nstitute.'~
The most concrete
conclusion that can he made about emission shifting in
DER credit trading programs for
NOx is that the gen-
eration of credits (equivalent to emission reductions)
occurred at the largest plants. The study found that in
four of the six states, over
90 percent of credits were
generated
by fewer than five sources that were typically
the largest emitters in the state: 94 percent in Texas,
96
percent in New Jersey and Massachusetts, and 99 per-
cent in New Hampshire. On the other hand, actual
credit use. while much less than credit
eeneration. was
DERs
1
1
32.908
1181
295
121
i
1
Bl
0
1
i
"
di,pcriud
dmung
il
large
numbcr ui sm~llcr
source,,
\\II~ tyr~icaliy IO-'<I)
tonr
bwng uwd b\
a
wurce in on?
year.
These data
confirm a general expectation about trad-
ing programs-that they will lead to emission reduc-
tions at the largest sources, where the capital cost of
pollution abatement strategies or controls can he
spread over the largest number of tons and hence lower
the per-ion cost of generating a credit.
B. Emissions Shiiing at the Area Level
The available regional data for DER programs only
allow a limited assessment of emission shifting at the
which give some indication of where emissions were
generated and used, and hence allows some assessment
of emission shifts." Figures
13
and 14 show that DER
programs have tended to reduce emissions in the most
polluted counties. To the extent they have shifted emis-
sions at all, the shift has been towards less polluted
counties. This pattern indicates that DER programs
have cooled hot spots to a limited extent, and led to
more evenly dispersed pollution in
hoth states.
New Jersey.
Figure 13 shows that 99 percent of DERs
in New Jersey were generated in counties with "severe"
status for ozone attainment, but 28 percent of the mod-
est DER use was in counties with "moderate" status.
This represents a small but slightly beneficial shift of
emissions from heavily polluted counties to less pol-
-
l.!..,
,,u,,,,,vn,.,I
l.<>,% l,,,t.l"rv
I~.'~~~!>SC<.I
l<k,.l
.< .!< ,,
cr<~:lt!
!..I
I,*!<,
.~,h,L~t,!<
.!
1
!
>u,,r2 ,,,,1e
I,',
.\n A>.%
uvr~ved
<!<,n>
:d
JI
12-15
luted counties, reducing rather than increasing emis-
sions concentrations.
Another indication in New Jersey that credit trading
did not contribute to hot spots was the simple element
of dispersion. Ninety-eight percent of credits were gen-
erated in two counties with severe
nonattainment
status-Hudson
and Mercer-whereas
credits were
used in
10 counties, none of which used more than 28
percent of the total credits
used.72
Figure 14
Texas B Generation and Use of NOx OERs
by County Ozone Attainment Status
I
i
DERs
i
38,527
'
0
1
2,241
i
Generated
1
(95%)
(5%)
Texas.
In Texas, while 38,527 DER credits were gen-
erated from 1997 to 2000, only
736
credits were used,
makine anv conclusions tentative. Aeain. DER eenera-
DERs
368
I
368
Used
(50%) I
(50%)
tion, e;iui;alent
to emissions reductrons; is disi;ropor-
tionately higher in severe nonattainment counties
0
where the environmental benefits are greatest: the lim-
ited use occurred in
hoth severe and moderate nonat-
tainment counties. Again, DER trading appears to have
slightly reduced emissions disproportionately more in
severely polluted regions than in less polluted ones (see
Figure 14).
VIII.
Conclusions
A review of the actual performance of trading pro-
grams shows that none of the programs evaluated has
resulted in regional shifts of emissions, and all trading
programs led to proportionately greater reductions
from the larger sources. Overall, the data from the pro-
grams reviewed in this report indicate that the effects of
trading have been slieht hut beneficial with reeards to
geographic hot spot; in the sense of smoothg out
emissions concentrations instead of concentrating
them, and cooling and not creating hot spots
A. Trading Has Not Led to Regional Concentrations
At the area level, the principal conclusion that
emerges from a review of the data is that trading
pro-
crams have eenerallv led to consistent behavior in the
;se of tradi2 mechanisms among regions. In the
SO,
program, the three large regions (Midwest, Northeast
and Southeast) behaved very similarly in both phases of
7'
Id.
ENVIRONMENT REPORTER
ISSN
00139211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
the program, with sources banking allowances to a
roughly equal extent during Phase
I and emitting
slightly over their allowance allocation in the initial
years of Phase
11. There was also a high degree of con-
sistency among states in the OTC NOx program, even
though
.
some states have only a handful of major
sources.
In particular, the concern that trading in the SO, pro-
gram could result in "upwind" sources in the Midwest-
ern region, disproportionately increasing emissions
that affect "downwind areas in the Northeast, did not
occur. In fact, due to the number of large plants in the
Midwest as well as Title N's allocation method, there
was a disproportionate decrease in emissions in the
Midwest, as Midwest sources contributed a dispropor-
tionate
60
percent to
80
percent of emissions reduc-
tion~.'~
The working of the trading program helped to
actually reduce emissions in this region with histori-
cally high SO, levels.
po\ver
An
aooronriate
>error,
.. .
\ignihc:tnt
conclusion
group
seems
uf
to
source,
be that
\r,ould
in the
bc
r-xpetir-d 11, ljehave s~n~~larly
in
a
cap-and trade pro-
gram
:~nd s~, ncg.lre the ~dca rhar thcre will be cmls-
;ions shifting. ~ui-ther research is needed on how many
sources need to be included in a trading program in or-
der for it to exhibit such consistency; the evidence from
the OTC program at a state level suggests that even a
few sources may be enough.
0.
Allocation Systems May Help Cut Concentrations
I ht d~sproponion;ite SO, emissl~rns !-educriuns In rhc
\1111\~~~1
ilppC31. 10 be 1.3~ltd /drg~I\. b,V Ille dl5pI'l>pl>r-
tionate reductions at larger plants, but also in part by
the method bv which allowances were allocated. The
>?
pi.ogr.lm allocared allowoncei to wurcer based
on
ihcli pa,! U~I~I/~I~IOJI
(11)
f'hils~.
II, baseline mmljtu rnul.
tlpl~ed by I
2
puunds oi
50.1
fhi5 method result\ in
dirty plaits receiving far fewer allowances in compari-
son to their past emissions than cleaner plants
of a simi-
lar size, since allowances are allocated based on past
heat input and not on past emissions. This method,
therefore, provides a positive incentive for plants with
the highest baseline emissions
(i.e. those using high-
sulfur Midwestern coal) to reduce pollution in areas
where it is most
'"
Sources in the eight state Midwestern region (see Figure
6) consticuted 42 ilercent of baseline emissions, hut contrib-
uted 60 percent of emissions reductions in Phase
11:
in an ex-
panded
ll-state Midwest region (Figure
8),
sources comprised
60 percent of baseline emissions and contributed 80 percent of
ell
redllrtinnc
...~. -- ~~~ ~ ~~
perfectly fluid markets, allocat~&s"~hould not m:ke a differ-
C. in Trading Programs, Largest Sources Reduce
Emissions Most
Another striking finding of the results is that emis-
sions trading programs have consistently led to signifi-
cantly greater emissions reductions at the
highest-
emitting plants.
In the SO, program's Phase
11,
the largest plants re-
duced emissions by
73
percent from baseline levels,
compared to a
48
percent reduction by the next largest
auartile.
41
uercent from the third auartile. and only
10
percent irom the smdle\r planri. 'l'his is hculusc ~hc
~!~.c~nonlic?
ui ~nstalllng capltal equipment lor pr<)ce,<
changes or controls provides the meatest financial re-
turnswhen installed-in the lareesi sources, leading to
disproportionate emissions
redhions at those souces.
This attribute of cap-and-trade programs is significant
in dispersing and not concentrating emissions, or cool-
ing and not creating hot spots.
-
D. Summary
Although trading programs do not guarantee reduc-
tions at each source, the above data show that they have
achieved consistent results between regions, and have
also led to proportionately greater reductions at
higher-
emitting plants. The SO, trading program in particular
significantly reduced existing hot spots by causing dis-
proportionate reductions in the Midwest. This finding is
attributable both to
the allocation method used in Title
IV and for the tendency in trading programs for the
largest sources to reduce emission the most. These
find-
ines indicate that can-and-trade orozrams similar to
thgse evaluated would not be expeke& to lead to emis-
sions concentrations or hot spots.
ence, as emissions reductions should he made where it is most
cost-effective to do so.
A possible explanation for the discrep-
ancy between the two programs is that the disparity in allo-
cated amounts was simply greater in the SO, program, leading
to a positive, albeit modest, response. Midwestern sources
re-
ceived 20 percent fewer allowances than those in other states
(a 60 percent versus a
40 percent reduction from baseline
emissions), twice the difference than in the
OTC
program. An-
other possible factor that requires further research is that,
given the autarkic response of firms
to regulation, allowance
allocation systems that differentiate the allocation to sources
by region may affect emissions results more
if the trading re-
gions segregate
firm territories instead of split them. There-
fore, allocation systems that split a state in two like the
OTC
program's Inner and Outer zones may make little difference in
firm behavior, as power companies that have plants through-
out the state would tend to create a system-wide compliance
strategy that would
not depend on the allowance allocations to
particular sources. Given that
firms behave autarkicly, we
might expect a more pronounced difference in emissions result
if trading programs make different allocations to different
states or regions that include all of a
firms territory, such
as
occurred in the SO, program.
57-04
COPYRIGHT
2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS. INC., WASHINGTON,
DC.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
ENVIRONMENT REPORTER
ISSN 0013-9211
BNA
5-7-04
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
5-7-04
COPYRIGHT " 2004 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS. INC.. WASHINGTON, O.C.
ER
ISSN 0013-9211
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Cmtrol:
Why Can-and-Trade Should Replace Rate
Standards for
Reeional Pollu~tS
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:iilC:lMyFileslACSH-Hg/Swift%2OEL1%20
31 ELR 10330
/
Environmental Law Reporter
/
copyright
O
2001
/
All rights reserved
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate
Standards for Regional Pollutants
Byron Swift
Byron Swift is a Senior Attorney and Director of the Energy and Innovation Center at the Environmental Law Institute.
His work addresses issues in designing environmental law to achieve high environmental quality while promoting
innovation and lowering costs.
He can be contacted by e-mail at swift@,eli.org. An overview of nitrogen oxides and
sulfur dioxide regulation of power plants in the 1990s will be published in
I4 TUL. ENVTL. L.J. I (2000). Background
research for this Article was supported in part by The Joyce Foundation and
A.W. Mellon Foundation. The author
thanks these foundations, and the many others who generously provided advice and data, with particular thanks to the
Clean Air Markets Division of the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Joel Bluestein, Dallas Burtraw. Denny
Ellennan, and Debra Knopman. The views expressed are of the author, and not necessarily those of the Environmental
Law Institute, The Joyce Foundation, or the
A.W. Mellon Foundation.
131 ELR 103301
I. Introduction
While current environmental laws provide us with an adequate environmental protection system, they must be reformed
if we hope to achieve an excellent one. This Dialogue examines regulation of nitrogen oxides (NO,) and sulfur dioxide
(SOz) in the power sector over the past years, and provides a direct comparison of the rate-based methods used in both
the Title
JV and neul source review (NSR) programs of the Clean Air Act (CAA)~ with cap-and-trade programs that
have been established for both pollutants. This examination reveals the need to move away from the use of end-of-pipe
rate standards and the
old sourcelnew source distinction in order to create an efficient and effective regulatory system
that embraces the principles of pollution prevention and sustainable development.
11.
An Overview of SO2 and NO, Regulation in the Power Generation Sector
A. Reguiufion of Existing Sources: Tiile IVand Ozone Transport Commission (OTC) Standards
Emissions of N4, and SO- from most existing power generation sources are regulated under Title IV of the
CAA
established in the
CAA
Amendments of 1990.2 Title IV creates two very different systems to achieve major reductions
in
SOz and NO, emission from utility sources: a national emissions cap and allowance trading approach for S@, and
rate-based standards for NO,. Northeastern states comprising the Ozone Transportation Region also initiated
NQ,
regulation in 1995 and instituted an emissions cap and allowance trading system for NO, in 1999. The results of these
programs are described below.
I. Emissions Cap and Allowance Trading Program for SQ
Electric utilities are responsible for 60% of national SO2 emissions,i and Title IV imposes a permanent cap on utility
SO2 emissions at 8.95 million tons, roughly one-half the 1980 baseline.* Title IV, unlike traditional regulation that
imposes source-specific rate limits, implements an industrywide mass standard known
as an emissions cap. The
emissions cap and allowance trading program for the
SQ program is divided in two phases. Phase I began in 1995 and
required the 263 dirtiest coal-fired electric-generating units (referred to as Table A units) to reduce their emissions to a
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:!/lC:/MyFileslACSH-Hg/Swift%ZOEL1%20
base level of 5.7 million tons of ~02.' Phase 11 implements a stricter standard in the year 2000, and requires all
generating units larger than 25 megawatts to reduce their emissions to the final cap amount.6
To implement the cap, allowances equivalent to a ton of
S@ are assigned to each affected generating unit based on
their generation rates from the historic base period of 1985-1987, scaled down so that the aggregate emissions equaled
the target emissions
cap.? Although the annual and the bonus allowances are allocated without charge to existing
sources, a limited number of allowances also are available for purchase through an annual U.S. Environmental
Protection Agency (EPA) auction.! Title IV, therefore, implements a zero new source standard, as any new generating
source must purchase all its needed
allowances.~ In another
131 ELR 103311
departure from traditional regulation. Title
1V allows individual sources to trade their unused allowances to other sources or bank them for future use.0
Finally, Title IV incorporates an extremely strict monitoring and compliance system. Monitoring is required by
continuous emissions monitoring
-
devices (CEMS) that collect data every 15 minutes, with consolidated data reported
hourly.fi The monitors must also regularly transmit data that indicates that the monitor is functioning properly. CEMS
are expensive, costing almost
$
1 million per stack.'" Compliance procedures are also strict and include an automatic
$
2,000 fine per ton and forfeiture of an additional ton of reductions.~
Utilities responded to the Title IV program by reducing SO2 emissions by eight million tons, almost 50% below their
1990
emissions level and30% below the cap in Phase I.' The most significant use of the flexibility mechanisms of
Title
1V was banking, or emitting below the standards and saving the allowances for later use. About 75% of total
allowances created were
banked,D as a more stringent cap on all units would be imposed in 2000. Another major use of
a flexibility provision was trading. which was used by 30 of the 51 firms for
intra-firm averaging.'6 Although trading
volume increased throughout the
program^ as firms became more comfortable with trading and some began to trade
for arbitrage purposes, only 3 of the 51 firms used inter-firm trading to emit over their allowance
allocation.^
Figure 1:1990-1999 SO2 Allocated Allowances and ~missionsB
[SEE ILLUSTRATlON IN ORIGINAL]
131 ELR 103321
A major story of Phase 1 compliance under the SO2 program was the low cost of compliance. This was due to the
flexibility of Title
IV, derived primarily from the cap approach, which allows greater flexibility than the rate-based
standards, and also the ability to trade
allowances.'o Initial expectations by industry in 1991 were for allowance prices
of $300 to
$
1,000 during Phase 1.2' In 1992 and 1993, the earliest signals began to show that prices would be
substantially
lower,a and EPA's first auction of allowances in March 1993, revealed prices at
$
131. Allowance prices
then continued in the
$
100 range until they began to climb toward $200 as Phase 11 approachedg
The lower cost of compliance was driven by cost reductions and innovation in both of the principal means of
compliance-the
use of low-sulfur coal and scrubbing, The widespread use of low-sulfur coal has been a major
component of compliance strategy for Phase I, resulting in over seven million tons of net reductions (over one-half of
net
reductions)."j This use was catalyzed by the flexibility afforded by Title IV, which allowed low-sulfur coal to
compete with scrubbing as a compliance method. This led to experimentation and innovation in fuel blending
techniques that allowed greater than expected use of low-sulfur western coals, and greater incentives to use eastern
low- and medium-sulfur coals. These innovations, together with reduction in rail costs due to competition among
railroads, lowered the cost premium for low-sulfur coal and
dra~natically increased their use, which has been a major
driving force in lowering the cost of compliance in Phase
I of Title IV.~
Scrubbing was the second principal strategy to reduce SO2 in Phase I, and accounts for 3.5 million tons of emissions
reductions (rising to 5.5 million tons if bonus allowances allocated to scrubbed units are
counted).% Scrubbers were
installed for 27 Table A
units,z promoted in part by the bonus allowances, although several firms canceled scrubber
contracts when the low prices for low-sulfur coal became apparent in the early 1990s. The cost of scrubbing also fell
significantly during the compliance period, due to innovation in design and materials as well as the significantly lower
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:ll/C:lMyFiles/ACSH-IIglSwift%2OEL1%2O2OOO,htm
need for redundancy to comply with Title 1V's annual standard, in comparison to previous scrubbers that had been built
to meet the new source standard.
Although the Phase
1 cap required only a moderate SO2 reduction of around 30%," the cap-and-trade approach exerted
continuous pressure to innovate and create lower cost reductions. The cap has prompted continuing innovation in fuel
blending techniques and rail infrastructure relating to low-sulfur coal, and also in scrubbing, the cost of which has
declined steadily since competition was created with low-sulfur
coa1.z me ability to trade allowances has led to a fully
integrated cost of sulfur in the coal market, integrating an environmental parameter into the price of coal. Finally, the
inonetization of environmental costs and benefits under the cap-and-trade approach has allowed the fuller integration of
environmental considerations into the regular financially based decisionmaking throughout a company.
Overall. the shift in Title
IV away from scrubber use and toward low-sulfur coal had economic, environmental, and
political consequences. The investment in rail infrastructure, innovation in fuel blending and rail transport, and
competition among railroads led to low compliance costs that benefitted both the industry and ratepayers. The principal
environmental benefit is the reduction and permanent cap on
SQ emissions, together with the greater political
possibility of further reductions given the low cost of compliance. Other environmental benefits of the move to cleaner
fuels include the benefits of pollution prevention, in avoiding the direct 1.5% energy loss and significant resource use
and waste disposal consequences of scrubbing. Political consequences were also significant, and include
the move from
unionized coal-mining jobs in midwestern stales with high-sulfur coal to western and Appalachian states with
low-sulfur coal. Notwithstanding these shifts, the success of the Title
IV SO2 cap-and-trade program in overachieving a
strict standard at low cost has led
some to include it among the most successful programs under the CAA.3
2. Title IV's Rate-Based Standards for NO,
Title
IV was also designed to reduce NO, emissions from utility boilers by two million tons below 1980 levels by the
year
2000.i'Title 1V established the first regulation of NO, faced by many existing power plants, as previously only
certain states had established NO, standards for older sources in order to meet ambient standards established under
Title 1 of the
CAA.~' However, instead of using an emissions
131
ELR
103331
cap and allowance trading system,
Congress required EPA to establish annual average emission limits in pounds per million British thermal unit
(IbtmmBtu) for coal-fired electric utility units based on the use of "low NO, burner technology."B The law further
contained flexibility provisions, including an annualized emissions rate period and the ability of firms to average the
emissions rates of units under their
control.2
Phase I ofthe NO, program applied to the 265 wall-fired and tangentially fired boilers included in Table A or
substitution units active on January
1,
1995, and lasted from 1996 to 1999.~
Phase I1 of the program started in 2000,
and includes all other affected
units.% The chart below shows the emissions limits applicable to different boiler types in
Phase
I and Phase 11 of the program. For wall-fired and tangentially fired boilers, the Phase 1 limits represent reductions
from their respective uncontrolled emissions levels of 0.95 and 0.65
lb/mm~tu.~
*5*Table 1. Title 1V NO, Standards by Boiler Type (lblmm~tu)"
Boiler Type
*2*Phase l *2*Phase 11
ii
Units
Standard
?i
Units Standard
Tangentially fired
135
0.45
308
0.40
Dry Bottom Wall-fired
130
0.50
299
0.46
Cell burners
36
0.63
Cyclones
(>I55 MW)
55
0.86
Vertically fired
28
0.84
Wet-bottom
(>65 MW)
26
0.84
Following a lawsuit on the meaning of
"low-NQ, burner technology" that delayed implementation for one year,Z the
NO, program proceeded smoothly with all 265 of the coal-fired units
affected under Phase I meeting the legal
requirements in each
year5 Most of the units-178
of 265--met the emissions rate limits specified in the regulations
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
fiie:lllC:lMyFileslACSH-HglSwifi%20ELi%20
through the installation of low-NO, burners, which, for many sources, was the least-cost method of meeting the
standard^.^ However, 10 units were granted less stringent alternative emissions limits because they could not meet the
emissions rate standard even after installing low-NO,
burners.42 Of the remainder, 23 met the emissions limit without
the need for burner modifications, and the rest
ofthe units continue to emit above the standards and were able to
comply through the law's averaging
provisions~ Overall, the flexibility provisions in the law, including the annual rate
standard and the ability to average emissions among a firm's units, allowed a relatively
low cost economic compliance,
with NOx reductions averaging $412 per ton in Phase 1.1'3
The reductions resulting from Phase I are shown graphically below. Overall, units lowered their average NO, emissions
rates to 0.40
IbImmBtu during Phase I, 43% below the 1990 average of 0.70 lb/mm~tu."5 This bas resulted in NO,
reductions of approximately 400,000 tons per year or 32% below 1990 levels, with reductions projected to rise to
2,060,000 tons per year during Phase
I1
that starts in 2000.B There is less ofa reduction in tons than in rates because
economic growth leading to higher
fiiel use by both Table A and substitution units. Unlike the capped
SOz
program,
NO, emissions would be expected to rise with increased
utilization!J
131 ELR 103341
Figure 2. Title N NO, Emission Rates for Phase I Units (1990-1999p
[SEE ILLUSTRATION IN ORIGINAL]
Co~npliance with the NO, program can be characterized in several ways. First, the program led primarily to the simple
retrofit of a known technology onto most boilers. Innovation led to cost reductions in low-NO, burner technology for
two kinds of boilers, but not a third, and did not lead to continuous drivers for improvement beyond the compliance
date. Second, firms made heavy use of the flexibility provisions, especially averaging-204 of the 265 affected units
were included in an averaging
plan.g A third characteristic was slight overcompliance with the standard, as Table A
firms emitted 11% below the standard to ensure a margin of
safety.50
3. OTC Cap-and-Trade in 1999 Forced Further Reductions at Existing Plants
In the
12 northeastern and Mid-Atlantic state$ NO, emissions from large power plants have been controlled not by
Title
IV, but by more stringent state regulations coordinated under the OTC. The OTC was created under the CAA
Amendments of 1990 to coordinate planning at a regional level to facilitate each state's efforts to reduce NO, in order
to attain the national ambient air quality standard for ground level ozone. In September 1994, every northeastern and
Mid-Atlantic state, except Virginia adopted a memorandum of understanding to achieve regional reductions of NO,
from power generators in three phases starting in
1995.52
In Phase I of the OTC program, states required sources to install reasonably available control lechnology (RACT), a
standard roughly equivalent to the Title IV standards but applying one year earlier.2 Pennsylvania required sources to
install low-NO, burners with separate
overfire air, and other states, such as New York and New Jersey, defined rate
standards that were slightly more stringent than the Title
IV standardsx Most states also allowed averaging among a
firm's facilities, creating standards slightly more stringent than but similar to Title
IV. In response, most sources added
combustion controls such
as low NO, burners andlor overfire air to their units.
131 ELR 103351
Phase 11 of the OTC program started in 1999, and nine OTC states established a NO, Budget Program involving an
emissions cap and allowance trading system similar to
EPA's SOz Acid Rain ~rogram.z The emissions cap required
912 electricity-generating units to reduce emissions by 55-65%
from their 1990 baseline of 417,444 tons.% Despite the
stringency of the standard, sources overcomplied by reducing emissions 20% below the cap
level.2 Compliance levels
were also very high, with only one source failing to meet its standard by one ton and, therefore, subjecting itself to an
automatic fine and two-ton penalty-
58
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S
Despite initial expectations that many sources would need to use expensive end-of-pipe controls such as selective
catalytic reduction (SCR) to achieve these deep reductions, the flexibility afforded by the cap-and-trade approach led to
unexpected results. One such result was that 126 of the 142 affected coal-fired units achieved NO, reductions up to
30% through operational changes alone, without significant capital
additions.2 The cap approach allowed compliance
through a number of technologies, including gas
reburn and selective noncatalytic reduction, and not only SCR. As a
consequence, allowance prices, after initial volatility at the start of the program in which prices ranged from $3,000 to
$
7.000 per ton, have settled down to less than the $500 to
$
1,000 range, significantly lower than estimated.@
B. New Source Standards
New plants or significant modification of existing plants are subject to a stringent federal NSR process, which requires
at a
minimum compliance with new source performance standards @~SPS)?~
Traditional NSPS establish emissions rate
standards for each power generation technology, such that more lenient standards are applied to dirtier technologies.
NSPS for NO, allow coal-fired boilers to emit twice the
NQ, as oil-fired ones, and three times that of gas-fired 0nes.G
In 1998, EPA established a new, fuel-neutral NSPS of 0.15 IbImmBtu for major modifications of existing sources, and
1.6
iblmegawatt hour (MWh) of electricity generated for new sources, the latter an innovative output-based standard
that provides a benefit to efficient
producers,~ However, this fuel-neutral NSPS rarely applies, as the case-by-case
oriented NSR process is more stringent and, therefore, controls new plant standards.
Under the
NSR process, regulators establish an emissions rate standard on a case-by-case basis, again based on the
power generation technology, such that more lenient standards are applied to dirtier technologies. The standard also
varies geographically: sources built in areas that have attained the ambient ozone standard set by EPA must prevent
significant deterioration of air quality, and install the best available control technology (BACT) for the type of plant
proposed considering "energy, environmental, and economic impacts and other
costs."g New plants in nonattainment
areas must meet the even more stringent lowest achievable emissions reduction (LAER) standard, which excludes
consideration of
cost.@ These strict standards are motivated both as a means to achieve ambient standards, and as a
mechanism to spur the development and application of new technologies.
I. New Source Standards for SO2
The 1970 CAA also established a stringent NSPS for new plants, limiting
SO2 emission rates to 1.2 IbImmBtu fol
coal-fired plants.% This had a dramatic effect on the industry, as emission rates from older plants were far higher, and
electric utilities began to focus research and operational efforts to extending the operating life of the old
"grandfathered" facilities. In the CAA Amendments of 1977, Congress created stricter NSPS by requiring new sources
to meet both the 1.2 pound standard
and
remove either 90% of SOz emissions from high-sulfur coal or 70% of the S@
emissions from low-sulfur coal.h7 This new standard requires utilities to install scrubbers at all new generating units,
removing much of the incentive to use low-sulfur coal and favoring political interests in using eastern high-sulfur coal.
I-lowever, by increasing the cost of new coal-fired plants, this requirement added to the incentives to extend the life of
the older and dirtier plants, and may have further aggravated the conditions that led to acid precipitation.
There are several aspects of the NSPS for SO2 that significantly restrict technology use and increase costs. First, it
requires sources to make a percentage reduction in potential emissions of
SO2 precluding compliance through
switching to low-sulfur fuel, as no matter how low the sulfur, the standard requires a further 70-90% reduction,
necessitating the
131
ELR
103361
use of an end-of-pipe technology such as scrubbing.68 Second, the standard
significantly increases the cost of the scrubber, which must be overbuilt to achieve a 90% (or 70%) reduction on a
continuous basis. As a consequence, the cost of an NSPS scrubber is far higher than needed to reduce sulfur, requiring
significant redundancy and typically a backup scrubber module in case the first one fails.
Ironically, the environment also does not benefit from the inflexible NSPS standard. Despite the costs imposed
by the
NSPS standard, it creates no net environmental benefits as total emissions are now governed by the emissions cap
under Title IV. Nor are there significant local benefits, as sources must already comply with
SO2 standards pursuant to
Title
I of the CAA that protect against local ambient concentrations. The continued use of the inflexible rate-based
methodology under the
SO? NSPS therefore makes little sense today when there is a national emissions cap on SOz.
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Cornrna~~d
Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
2. New Source Kate Standards for NO, Have Created an Uneven Regulatory Framework and Differential Business
Drivers
A major problem with NO, new source standards is that by differentiating between old and new plants. they create a
significant bias toward old sources that only need to meet a relatively weak standard, while new clean sources face a
very stringent one. This problem is exacerbated in the power sector due to long capital life and the great differences in
generating technologies. Older largely coal-fired plants emit NO, at levels of
100 to over 1,000 parts per million (ppm)
of exhaust volume, even though some could reduce NO, at prices as low as $300 a
ton.@ However, new plants are
virtually ail gas-fired10 and
far cleaner than coal plants, and the stringent NSR standards require them to reduce their
already low NO, emissions to 9 ppm, or in some states
2 ppm.2 This requires investments in end-of-pipe controls that
cost from $2,500 to over
$
10,000 per ton of NO, reductions and that can discourage investment in newer clean
As shown in the table below, NO, regulation of power plants in the 1990s created a highly uneven regulatory
framework. Because rate standards were set at differing levels for the different base technologies, they create a perverse
situation in which the greater the amount of
NO, emitted by a power technology, the more lenient the rate standard.
The table also reveals the great disparity between the standards for old and new sources, and also how
technology-by-technology standards have imposed the highest costs on the cleanest sources.
*4*Table 2. Differential Effects of Current Law on NO,
Reductions From
*4*Generating Technologies (1996-1999p
*4*Differential Standards for NO, Reductions From Generating
*4*Technologies (1 996- 1999):
*3*01d Sources (Title 1V
RACT)
Cyclone
Wall-Fired T-Fired
Coal
Coal
Coal
Uncontrolled
NOY
1.50
0.95
0.65
(IbimmBtu)
Legal Standard
none
0.50
0.45
(IblmmBtu)
Cost Per Ton
none
$150
$400
*4*Table 2. Differential Effects of Current Law on NO,
Reductions From
*4*Generating Technologies (1996-199912
*4*Differential Standards for NO, Reductions From Generating
*4*Technologies (1996-1999):
*3*New Sources
(BACTILAER)
New Coal
Uncontrolled NO,
(IblmmBtu)
Legal Standard
New
Gas New Gas
Large
Small
0.05
0.10
(IblmmBtu)
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S.
Cost Per Ton
$565 (SCR)
$
10,000
$2,500
+
131 ELR 103371
NSR also applies when plants undergo significant modifications, and EPA has filed lawsuits against eight companies
asserting that their older plants should be subject lo NSR because they have made major modifications. However, even
if a source has undergone NSR, years or decades may elapse before the plant is subject to the standards again, during
which time there is no incentive to improve. Another problem is that these standards divert research attention away
from identifying and developing new, cleaner power sources, to how to achieve pollutant reductions and extend the life
of older sources without triggering NSR. This leads to a fundamental lack of alignment of the objectives promoted by
CAA and objectives of a sound clean energy policy.
111.
Findings
A. Problems With the Methodology of Using Rate Standards
There are several key problems with the rate standards for NO, and SO;. used under Title IV and new source
standards.These problems preclude their efficient or effective operation and are especially pronounced in sectors, such
as power generation, with long capital life.
1. Emissions Rate Standards Do Not Force a Move Toward Cleaner Technologies
One of the chief problems with emissions rate standards for NO, under both Title
IV and new source standard is that
they are individually set for each specific generation technology. Different standards are set depending on the kind of
fuel used, and specific boiler or turbine technology used. Therefore, Title
IV's Phase I NO, standards were 0.50
IbimmBtu for wall-fired boilers, 0.45 IbimmBtu for tangentially fired boilers, and various other boilers were completely
exempt; under Phase
I1 NO, standards V~IY from 0.86 to 0.40 1bimm~tu.E Under NSR, new gas technologies face
standards at or lower than 0.05
lb/mmBty an order of magnitude lower than the standards for old coal plantsz Such
standards create no incentive to move from dirtier to cleaner technologies. Yet in the power sector, the fundamental
answer to solving pollution problems is precisely to move to cleaner, less polluting technologies.
2. Rate Standards Apply Only at a Discrete Point in Time, Limiting Compliance Methods
Another key problem with the current rate standard approach is that they require reductions only once: for new plants,
at the time the plant is built or undergoes a major modification, and for existing plants, at the date Title
IV applied.z
This limits compliance options to those capital or process equipment choices made at the time the plant is built or
modified, and eliminates the possibility of compliance through changes in management practices, fuels, or any other
operational decisions after a plant is built. This harkens back to an older view of pollution, that there is a single known
technology "fix"
tliat can be implemented once. The reality is that technology is ever-evolving, and there are numerous
technologies and management practices that can reduce pollution; a good regulatory system needs to provide firms with
the incentives to implement them.
There are three major negative consequences of applying a rate standard at only one time, such as when a plant is built
or at a certain date. The first is
tliat such a standard provides firms with no incentive to take advantage of future
technology advances. A firm does not have to implement anything more after the date it is permitted, even if
a
technological breakthrough means that it could inexpensively reduce pollution an additional amount. This is precisely
what has happened with cyclone boilers. as after the regulatory standard was issued, the industry discovered how to
cheaply reduce NO, emissions in cyclones far below the standard, However, firms had no incentive to do so, thereby
allowing
high-emittingboilers to continue to pour pollution into the air.
The second negative consequence is that the
CARS new source standards only promote compliance through decisions
about capital equipment, and not through ongoing operational or management decisions. Many
N4 reduction
technologies, such as gas
reburn and overfire air, are incremental, and can be adjusted to achieve various rates of NO,
control depending on the cost of inputs and other parameters. Indeed, the first year of application of the OTC
cap-and-trade for NO, in northeastern states revealed that once a rnarket incentive was created to reduce NO,
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:l!iC:!MyFiles!ACSH-Hg/Swift%ZOEL1%2
emissions, firms found ways to lower NO, by up to 30%
at
existing units, and without significant capital addition^.'^
Achieving NO, reductions through operational changes can be highly effective, and may be essential in order to reduce
NO, to very low levels. Promoting such changes requires that regulatory systems move beyond the current rate-based
approach, which provide no incentives to go beyond initially established limits.
A third major but longer term consequence of requiring compliance only through periodic changes in rates is its chilling
effect on research and development. Since the rate standard creates no continuous driver to lower emissions, firms do
not invest continuously in research and development to enhance environmental quality, because there is no compliance
benefit in doing so. Instead, the periodic effort to lower the rate standards becomes a political issue, with industry
battling through its lawyers to make sure the rate standard is as lenient as possible, and then to use existing
technologies for compliance. As demonstrated best by the cyclone boiler
situation,x when the rate standard is then
announced,
131
ELR
103381
there is a flurry of research activity on how to reach the standard at least cost, after which
the research effort subsides again.
3. Emissions Rate Standards Restrict Compliance Technologies and Promote End-of-Pipe Solutions Instead of
Pollution Prevention and Cleaner Processes
A fundamental problem with rate standards is that by focusing on end-of-pipe rate reductions, they may restrict
technology choice, and inherently favor compliance practices through end-of-pipe pollution controls instead of the
other two compliance methods--cleaner inputs or fuels and cleaner processes. Both of the latter are more aligned with
pollution prevention principles.
The following table compares the technologies permitted under various
S@ standards, and the estimates of compliance
cost
using those standards. It shows that for identical pollutant reductions. more inflexible regulatory standards can
significantly increase costs. A technology prescription, such as one mandating that scrubbers gain a 10 million ton
reduction, is the least flexible and was estimated to cost $7 million? Equally inflexible was the 1978 NSPS because it
required a rate reduction in potential emissions of
70-90%, which meant that one had to scrub no matter how clean the
coal.@ Somewhat more flexible was the 1971 NSPS, with a percentage concentration rate standard that allowed the use
of either a scrubber or compliance coal." Title
IV's cap-and-trade program-passed
in 1990-allows any compliance
method.
*4*Table 3. Technologies Permitted Under Different SOz
*4*Regulatory Systems"
Regulatory
Method
Technology
Emissions Limit Emissions Limit
Prescription
Using Percentage Using Percentage
Reduction
Concentration
Technologies
.
scrubbers
.
scrubbers
.
scrubbers
Permitted
Estimated
Compliance
Cost in Billions
Per Year
*3*Table 3. Technologies Permitted Under Different SOz
*3*Regulatory Systems8:
Regulatory
Method
Technologies
Permitted
.
limited use
low-sulfur
coal
$7
$
4.5
Emissions Cap Emissions Cap
Without Trading With Trading
.
scrubbers
.
scrubbers
.
major use low-
.
major use low-
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file://lC:/MyFiles/ACSH-Hg/Swifi~2OEL1%2O2OOO.htm
Estimated
Compliance
Cost in Billions
sulfur coal
sulfur coal
.
fuel blending
.
fuel blending
,
no backup
.
no backup
necessary
necessary
,
demand side
.
demand side
management
management
.
power shifting
.trading
$
2.5
$
1.2
Per Yeas
J31
ELR
103391
The regulatory agency applying a rate standard may add to the inflexibility inherent in rate standards by favoring
pollutant reductions gains through end-of-pipe controls over those achieved through pollution prevention. Over the past
decade, major technological advances in natural gas turbines have reduced their uncontrolled NO, emissions from over
100 ppm to the very
Low 9-15 ppm range.8' This has achieved a 90% pollution reduction, yet this may not count when a
regulatosy body applies a standard like BACT or LAER. Some states applying these standards only recognize a 90%
reduction achieved though end-of-pipe control equipment such as
SCRs. and do not count what has been achieved
through pollution prevention or process change
@
4. Emissions Rate Standards Create High Transaction Costs and a Culture of Conflict Between Regulators and the
Regulated Industry
Typical permitting processes applying new source rate-based standards under the
CAA typically takes one and one-half
years or longer, creating high administrative costs to
governments and major opportunity costs for fisms that may be
siting new clean plants. Under this process, a government regulator must make a specific determination of
what specific
technology meets the regulatory standards or is the "best available," pitting regulators against the applicant in a series
of factual issues
85
Title IV's NO, standards resulted in litigation that delayed the program one year due to a conflict
between industry and regulators on the applicable technology, and the NSR process is time- and resource-intensive.
However, the gain to the environment may be zero or slight if the plant is a modem gas plant, as
NO, and SOz
emissions are minimal, and they would be expected to create benefits by displacing power from dirtier sources. In
addition, in nonattainment areas, any resulting emissions must be offset anyway, creating no net environmental benefit
from these lengthy procedures.
Regulations do not have to be this way. Major environmental benefits can be achieved without transaction costs under
technology-neutral approaches such as the emissions cap and allowance trading system. Both the Acid Rain Program's
SO2 cap and the OTC NO, cap create major emissions reductions and a zero new source standard without any lengthy
permitting procedures (transactions take less than 24 hours) or conflict between regulator and regulated. These
approaches redirect business efforts away from contesting regulatory authority toward competing in the marketplace.
D.
Problems Relating to ihe Disparig in Standards Between Old and New Plants
A fundamental strategy in our CAA has been to impose strict standards on new plants, while old plants are exempted or
subject to lenient
requireinents. These new source standards are designed both to reduce ambient pollution levels, on
the assumption it
will be cheaper to achieve reductions at new plants instead of old plants, and as a technology-forcing
mechanism to encourage the development of cleaner processes. The effectiveness of these standards is assessed below
for
NO, reductions. as the lack of construction of new coal plants means there are few new SO2 sources.
1, New Source Standards I-lave Failed to Efficiently Reduce Ambient Pollution Levels
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S
A basic assumption behind new source standards is that it will be less expensive to attain the emissions reductions
needed to achieve ambient levels through new source standards. This assumption appears fundamentally flawed in the
NO, case, and based on a static concept of technology change. Due to fundamental technology changes in power
generation, the disparity in rate standards between old and new plants now results in perverse incentives for attaining
clean energy. Today, virtually all new power plants use gas-fired turbine technology@ and are
both more efficient and
far cleaner than coal-fired units---even without controls. Modern gas combined cycle plants emit virtually no
SDL,
particulates or air toxics, and NO, emission levels are around 0.05 IbImmBtu, well below the NSPS and 10 to 40 times
lower than that of coal
units.= Therefore, as shown in the above Figure 3. there is actually an inverse relationship
between the age and cleanliness of plants and the costs of added NO, reductions. Contrary to the initial supposition that
it would be cheaper to achieve significant reductions at new plants versus older ones, technology change has meant
that
significant reductions are available only at old plants and are also far cheaper there.
2.
New Source Standards Force Only Limited Kinds of Innovation
The record of new source standard and forcing innovation is more complex. New source standards have led to
development of new technologies, including improvements in SCR technology and innovative control technologies.
such as
SCONOX~
131
ELR
103401
and XONON.E
They have also contributed to a collaborative federal-industry
effort to develop cleaner and more efficient gas turbines, to which federal research also played a large
role.% However,
it has also suppressed innovation. The distinction between old and new plants has led firms to continue to use highly
polluting old plants, and has restrained upgrades or efficiency investments because they might trigger NSR. As a
consequence, virtually all research funds spent by the principle utility research coalition, EPRI (formerly the Electric
Power Research Institute), is to improve the performance of existing units, whereas most federal research funds are to
develop new and cleaner
technologies.~ Secondly. the process of governmental approval of specific firm technology
choices has led to a situation that has virtually eliminated venture capital from the environmental technology
field.%
3. NSR Creates No Net Benefits in Nonattainment Areas or Under an Emissions Cap Approach
A final irony is that in a cap-and-trade situation, or in nonattainrnent areas where the CAA requires any new source to
fully offset its emissions with matching reductions from existing sources, there are no actual environmental benefits
as
there are no net NO, reductions even after the very high costs imposed by NSR.~~
C. Cap-and-Trade Puo~ams Achieve a Results-Oriented Approach
Fortunately, there are solutions for each of the significant problems created by NO, and SDL rate regulations. The best
and most comprehensive solution would be to replace existing standards with a stringent emission cap and allowance
trading system, created on a national or regional basis, that includes all
sources.~ This solution would not only be
extremely effective environmentally, but also would eliminate virtually all of the problems mentioned above that are
caused by the use of rate standards, because cap-and-trade programs:
*
create a consistent standard applicable to both old and new plants;
*
do not discriminate by creating different standards for different technologies;
*
create continuous drivers for improvement and innovation;
*
allow business flexibility to choose differing compliance approaches:
*
have effective monitoring of emissions;
*
achieve hi* levels or 100% compliance; and
*
minimize transaction costs and conflict
Steps are being taken to implement cap-and-trade approaches, including existing programs such as the Acid Rain
Program, the OTC NO, cap-and-trade system in the
h'ortheast, and the pending EPA state implementation plan call that
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:l//C:/MyFilcs/ACS~f-HgiSwift%20EL1%202000.htm
would extend an NO, cap-and-trade system to at least 19 eastern states.% In addition, "4-pollutant" bills proposed in
Congress would establish stringent national cap-and-trade standards for
SOz. NO,, and carbon dioxide, and address
mercury
reductions.% These would eliminate the grandfathering problem and create a uniform standard applied to all
covered units. while promoting compliance through pollution prevention.
The major benefits of a good cap-and-trade system are that it enacts a stringent and pennanent limit, which serves
society's interest in pollution reductions, while allowing the widest possible breadth of compliance options, hence
reducing costs. It removes government from case-by-case decisionmaking about technologies, freeing business to
experiment without liability. Cap-and-trade systems eliminate all discrimination between old and new plants and
between technologies because
all face equal incentives to reduce.z It performs far better than a rate-based system in
regards to
131
ELR
103411
both cost and innovation, principally because government no longer needs to predict where
innovation may occur as they do in a rate system. The cap-and-trade system places this burden on the regulated entities.
A cap-and-trade approach also encourages greater innovation for several reasons. Perhaps the most important is that the
uniform standard exerts pressure on all to innovate, as all sources are equally covered under the standard. There are no
exceptions, waivers, or lower standards for certain technologies that characterize most rate systems, such as the Title
IV
NO, program, in contrast to the S@ program. This maximizes the breadth of innovation and allows unexpected
innovation. Second, the pressure to innovate is continuous, driven both by the lack of growth in the cap and the
opportunity to market allowances. Both give firms reasons to continuously seek lower emissions, unlike rate systems
where there is no incentive to go beyond the rate limit. Third, the opportunity to use allowances softens the risk of
failure in experimentation, while the cap assures achievement of environmental goals.
Another key benefit of cap-and-trade programs is their record of effective monitoring and near 100% compliance. In
five years, the Acid Rain Program for
S@ has achieved 100% compliance every year, and in the first year of the O'TC
NO, cap-and-trade program, there was only one exceedance of one ton, leading to a swift and automatic penalty%
Yet another benefit is that cap-and-trade programs minimize transaction costs. Instead of a protracted dispute between
firms and government about what technology is most appropriate, firms must simply comply and be able to show the
government that at year-end they have enough allowances to cover emissions. The government role changes
appropriately and dramatically from choosing technologies to assuring compliance. The environmental integrity of the
program is assured by the reductions made through the emissions cap, which never grows.
A negative aspect that some believe may occur with cap-and-trade programs is that the trading may shift the locus of
emissions, potentially causing areas of higher localized pollution levels. In reality, it is difficult to see why
cap-and-trade systems should have any greater effect in this regard than rate standards, which themselves
ailow great
local variability as they do not control plant size, siting, or utilization. In particular, this should not be of concern with a
regional pollutant, or if the total reductions are sufficiently great that everyone benefits. In addition, an analysis of the
first four years of the Acid Rain Program's
S@ cap-and-trade program showed that regional movements of allowances
were minimal
(3% of all allowances used), and that trading may even have helped cool hot spots.2
IV. Conclusion
Experience with rate-based approaches for NO, and SO2 regulation in the power generation sector reveals inflexibility
in their application that does not help to reach environmental benefits. Key problems include the disparities created for
different technologies and between old and new plants, which creates strong economic incentives to use dirtier
technologies and against the installation of new plants; their restriction of technology choice; and tendency to limit
innovation to end-of-pipe controls. Emissions cap and allowance trading systems now in place for both
SOz and NO,
have been able to effect a strict environmental standard while avoiding the inflexibility of rate standards, and are
more
aligned with pollution prevention goals. Moving from rates standards toward cap-and-trade programs appears essential
to meet the goals of a clean energy policy and to attaining the
rnultipollutant reductions benefits from switching to
cleaner new power sources.
-
1.42 U.S.C.
$3
7401-7671q. ELRSTAT. CAA
$3
101-618.
-
2.
Title IV of the CAA Amendments of 1990, Pub. L. No. 101-549, tit. IV, 104 Stat. 2399 (codified at 42 U.S.C.
5s
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:///C:~MyFiles/ACSH-HgiSwift~20ELI%202000.h~
7651-76510, ELR STAT. CAA
$5
401-416), was designed to address the problem of acidification of lands and water
bodies caused by acid deposition from emissions of
SQ and NO,. Emissions of these substances also cause significant
health problems in the formation of fine particulates and urban ozone, which although recognized at the time of passage
of the
I990 Amendments were not emphasized.
3. U.S. EPA, NATIONAL AIR POLLUTANT EMISSION TRENDS
1990-1998 3-10 (1999) [hereinafter EMISSION
TRENDS].
-
4.
U.S. EPA, 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT. ACID RAIN PROGRAM 5 (2000) (EPA-430-R-00-007) [hereinafter
EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORTJ; EMISSION TRENDS.
supra
note 3, at 3-12 (utility SO2 emissions recorded at
17.5 million tons in 1980).
-
5. The level of the Phase I cap was reached by multiplying an emission rate of 2.5 pounds of
SO2 per million British
thermal unit (IbImmBtu) times utilization in the baseline years.
-
6. The level
ofthe Phase 11 cap of 8.95 million tons was reached by multiplying an emissions rate of 1.2 IbImmBtu S@
times baseline utilization. The 1.2 IbImmBtu emission rate has historical significance, as it is the rate standard that has
been required for new coal-fired power plants since 1970. Because bonus allowances of 530,000 tons per year will be
issued from 2000 to 2009, the cap in those years will equal 9.48 million tons.
7. In addition to these basic allowance allocations, Title
IV also allocates 3.5 million bonus allowances over the first
Gars of the program to encourage the use of scrubbers, and 300,000 bonus allowances to reward efforts to develop
alternative energy sources. 42 U.S.C.
5
7651c(g), ELR STAT. CAA 5 404(g).
-
8.
Id 5
765 1, ELR STAT. CAA
5
401.
-
9. Id 5
7651 b(e), ELR STAT. CAA
5
403(e).
-
10.
Id.
-
1 I. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4, at 17-18;
see also
40 C.F.R. pt. 75 (2000)
-
12. A. DENNY ELLERMAN ET AL.. MARKETS FOR CLEAN AIR: THE U.S. ACID RAlN PROGRAM 250 (2000)
[hereinafter ELLERMAN 20001.
-
13.42 U.S.C.
5
7651j, ELR STAT. CAA
5
41 1.
-
14. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4. In addition to the actual reductions of almost 8 million tons, 3.5
million extension allowances were allocated as bonus allowances, which together with other bonus programs created an
11.6 million allowance bank at the end of 1999.
Id
-
15. ENVIRONMENTAL LAW INST., ANALYSIS OF EPA 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORTS (on file with
author) [hereinafter ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS].
-
17. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4, at 1 l
-
18. ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,
supra
note 15.
-
19. U.S. EPA. ACID RAlN COMPLIANCE REPORTS 1995-1997; EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note
4.
-
20. ELLERMAN 2000,
supra
note 12; Dallas Burtraw
&
Byron Swift,
A New Standard ofPerjormance: An Analysis of
the Clean Air Act's Acid
Rain
Program,
26 ELR 1041 I (Aug. 1996).
-
21. An industry poll showed widespread expectations of allowance prices on the order of $300 to $735 for Phase
I and
$
500 to
$
1,000 for Phase 11 in June-July 1991, falling to $200 to $550 for Phase I and $300 to
$
700 for Phase I1 by
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:lllC:/MyFileslACSH-HglSwifl%20EL1%202000.htm
October-November 1991. Ian M. Torrens et al.,
The 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments: Overview, Utilil)) Industry
Responses,
andStrategic Implications,
17 ANNUAL REV. OF ENERGY
&
THE ENV'T 220 (1992);
see also
ELLERMAN 2000,
supra
note 12, at 232.
-
22. The first was a trade of 10,000 allowances from Wisconsin Power
&
Light to the Tennessee Valley Authority at
$
265. Matthew L. Wald,
T. KA. Buys Allowance to Emit a Chemical in Acid Rain,
N.Y. TIMES, May 12, 1992,at Al;
Frank Edward Allen,
Tennessee Valley Authority Is Buying Pollution Riglzts From Wisconsin Power,
WALL ST. J.,
May
11. 1992. The second was a trade of 25,000 allowances from ALCOA to Ohio Edison for $300 per allowance.
Joan E.
Rigdon,
ALCOA Unit Arranges
S
7.5
Million Sale ofPoNufion Allowances to Ohio Edison,
WALL ST. J.. July
1, 1992.
-
23. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4, at 10.
-
24. ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,
supra
note 15.
-
25. ELLERMAN 2000,
supra
note 12.
-
26. ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,
supra
note 15.
27. U.S. DOE, ENERGY INFORMATION ADMIN., ELECTRIC POWER ANNUAL vol. 11, tbl. 30 (detailing flue gas
zulfurization capacity in operation at U.S. electric utility plants as of December 1999).
28,
The 1985-1987 baseline level of Phase I units is about 10 million tons, and the average Phase I cap was
approximately 6.8 million tons (not counting bonus allowances), for a
33% reduction. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE
REPORT,
~upra
note 4, at 7.
-
29. ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,
supra
note 15
30. Id.;
Burtraw
&
Swift, supranote 20.
-
31. Acid Rain Program; Nitrogen Oxides Emission Reduction Program-Phase
11 Final Rule, 61 Fed. Reg. 671 11 (Dec.
19, 1996) [hereinafter Phase I1 Final Rule].
-
32. Although
some states established these as early as 1972, most states did not emphasize NO, reductions until
scientific evidence began to indicate reducing NO, would be the most effective way to reduce urban ozone.
NATIONAL RESEARCH
COCWCIL, RETHINKING THE OZONE PROBLEM IN URBAN AND REGIONAL AIR
POLLUTION (1991).
-
33.42 U.S.C.
5
7651. ELR STAT. CAA
5
401
Id. 5
7651f, ELR STAT. CAA
§
407.
-
35. These units, known as Group 2 boilers, include cell, cyclone, and wet-bottom boilers.
Id
-
36. Phase I1 includes both wall-fired and tangentially fired (Group I) boilers not covered in Phase 1 and other types of
boilers (Group 2 boilers),
See
Phase I1 Final Rule,
supra
note 31. Since the units included in Phase 1 have already made
their boiler modifications, they are permanently grandfathered at the lower Phase
I standards and not the more stringent
Phase
I1 standards. 42 U.S.C.
5
7651f, ELR STAT. CAA
§
407.
-
37. U.S. EPA, COMPILATION OF AIR POLLUTANT EMISSION FACTORS AP-42 (1990).
3X.
42 U.S.C.
5
7651f, ELR STAT. CAA
5
407
-
39.
Alabama Power Co. v. EPA, 40 F.3d 450, 25 ELR 20166 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (vacating Phase I NO, final rule)
-
40. EPA1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4, at 10.
-
41. ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,supra note 15.
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S
-
42. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4, at 10. The process for approving these alternative emissions
limits is still not complete for any unit.
-
43. ELI
1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,
supra
note 15
3
See Phase I1 Final Rule,
supra
note 31.
5
EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4, at app. C-2. The range of emissions rates for the affected
boilers has also been reduced, from 1990 baseline emissions ranging from 0.26 to 1.21
lb/mmBtu to a range from 0.13
to 0.81
lb/mmH1u in 1999.
Id
45. ELI 1995-1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT ANALYSIS,
supra
note 15.
49. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT.
supra
note 4, at app. C-1
50,
Id
at 14. For Table A units, average emissions were 0.43 1bIminBtu during the 4 years of the program, 11% below
the
average limitation of 0.49 lb per mmBtu. Emissions rates of Table A units gradually moved lower during the Phase
I, from 0 45
IbImmBtu in 1996, to 0.42 IbImmBtu in 1999. Id
51. The OTC comprises the states of Connecticut, Delaware, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, New
Sk;sey, New York. Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, and Vermont; the northern counties of Virginia; and the District of
Columbia.
-
52. Memorandum of Understanding Among the States of the Ozone Transport Coinmission on Development of a
Regional Strategy Concerning the Control of Stationary Source Nitrogen Oxide Emission (signed Sept. 27. 1994),
available at
http-
[hereinafter OTC MEMORANDUM OF UNDERSTANDING]. Phase I included
the installation of reasonably available control technology
(RACII).
a
id.
-
54. Pennsylvania law defines RACT for large coal-fired units as "the installation of low NO, burners with separate
overfire air." 25 PA. CODE 8 129.93 (b)(l) (2000). New Jersey requires utility boilers to meet the following standards:
tangentially fired: .38
IbImmBtu; wall-fired; .45 IblmmBtu; and cyclone .55 IblmmBtu. 7 N.J. ADMN. CODE
$
27-19.4 (2000). New York State RACT regulations set standards for wet-bottom coal-fired tangential plants at 0.42
Ibs./mmBtu. and for wall-fired at 0.45 lbs./mmBtu. N.Y. COMP. CODES R. ®S. tit. 6, 5 227-2.4 (2000).
-
55. OTC Memorandum of Understanding,
supra
note 52. Under this program, budget sources were allocated
allowances by their state government. Each allowance permits a source to emit one ton of NO, during the summer
period (May through September). Allowances may be bought, sold. or banked. Any person may acquire allowances and
partic~pate in the trading system. Each budget source must comply with the program by demonstrating at the end of
each control period that actual emissions do not exceed the amount of allowances held for that period. However.
regardless of
the number of allowances a source holds, it cannot emit at levels that would violate other federal or state
limits,
e.g., new source performance standards (NSPS), Title IV, or NO, RACT.
-
56. U.S. EPA, 1999 OTC NO, BUDGETPROGRAM COMPLIANCE REPORT (Mar. 27,2000).
-
59. Joel Bluestein, Energy and Environmental Analysis. Inc., OTR NO, Market: Lessons Learned (1999) (unpublished
report presented at Emissions Marketing Associates in October 1999) (on file with author); GAS RESEARCI-I INST.,
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control. Why Cap-and-Trade Should Rcplace Rate S...
file:/llC:~MyFiles/ACSH-Hg/S~ift%2OELI%202OOO.htm
LOW COST OPTIONS FOR ACHIEVING DEEP NO, REDUCTIONS (2000),
available at
http://www.gri.org.
60. Alternative technologies are described in the Gas Research institute's report on
Low Cost Options for Achieving
&I
NOx Reductions
See GAS RESEARCH INST.
supya
note 59. Compliance cost is described in U.S. EPA, 1999
OTC NO, BUDGET PROGRAM COMPLIANCE REPORT,
slpa
note 56.
-
61.42 U.S.C.
5
7479(3), ELR STAT. CAA
5
169
62. The initial NSPS for power plant boilers established NO, emissions limits of 0.50 to 0.80 IbImmBtu for coal-fired
bailers, 0.30 lb/mmBtu fir oil-fired boilers. and 0.20 IbI~nmBtu for gas-fired boilers. 40 C.F.R. pts. 60.44, 60.44a
(2000).
-
63.
Id
pt. 60.44a(d); Revision of Standards of Performance for Nitrogen Oxide Emissions From New Fossil-Fuel Fired
Steam Generating Units; Revisions to Reporting Requirements for Standards of Performance for New Fossil-Fuel Fired
Steam Generating Units. 61 Fed. Reg. 49442 (Sept. 16, 1998) (final rule).
-
64.42 U.S.C.
$5
7475,7479(3), E1.R STAT. CAA
$5
165, 166(3)
-
6.5. Id
$
7503(a)(2), ELR STAT.
CAA
5
173(a)(2)
66.40 C.F.R. pt. 60.44 (2000).
67.
Id.
pt. 60.44a.
fiIL
In Sierra Club v. Costle, 657 F.2d 298, 1 I ELR 20455 (D.C. Cir. 1981), the court affirmed that a utility could not
use low-sulfur coal to create equivalent reductions. It interpreted the rate-based standard and held that:
In no instance, however, can a plant reduce emissions by less than
70 percent of potential uncontrolled
emissions.
. . .
There is no dispute that the 70 percent floor in the standard necessarily means that, given
the present state of pollution control technology, utilities will have to employ some form of flue gas
desulfurization
("FGD" or "scrubbing") technology.
Id
at 3 16
&
n.38, 11 ELR Digest at 20455.
-
69.
See
Table 2
infa
70. U.S. DOE, ANNUAL ENERGY OUTLOOK 2000 (1999) [hereinafter DOE ANNUAL ENERGY OUTLOOK
zo00].
-
71. U.S. EPA, RACTIBACTiLAER CLEARlNGHOUSE ANNUAL REPORT FOR 1998: A COMPILATION OF
CONTROL TECHNOLOGY DETERMINATIONS (June 1998) (EPA 4561R-98-004) [hereinafter U.S. EPA
CLEARINGHOUSE REPORT FOR
19981.
72.
See
Table 2
infia
73. U S. EPA, COMPILATION OF AIR POLLUTANT EMISSION FACTORS AP-42 (1998); Phase I1 Final Rule,
supra
note 31; Joel Chalfin, General Electric Power Plant Systems, Gas Turbine Emissions (1999) (unpublished
presentation) (notes on file with author); Leslie Witherspoon &Ken Smith, NO, Control Technology Options and
Development Activity for Mid-Range Natural Gas Fired Turbines
(1999) (unpublished presentation) (notes on file with
author).
-
74.40 C.F.R. pts. 76.5-76.7 (2000).
-
75. U.S. EPA CLEARINGHOUSE REPORT FOR 1998,supra note 71
-
76. Title IV required sources affected by Phase I to make reductions by Januay 1,1995, and for all other sources must
make reductions by January I, 2000. 42 U.S.C.
$5
7651c(a). 7651d(a), ELR STAT. CAA
$5
404(a), 405(a). NSK
Sof 18
12/29:2005 11:49
AM
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:///C:/MyFileslACSH-Hg/Swift~2OELI%202OOO.htm
applies when a plant is built or undergoes a major modification.
Id 5
7479(1)-(2), ELR STAT. CAA
$
l69(1)-(2).
77-
GAS RESEARCH INST.,
supra
note 59; Bluestein,
supra
note 59.
-
78.
See
Dave O'Connor et al., Electric Power Research Inst., The State of the Art in Cyclone Boiler NO, Reduction
(1 999) (unpublished presentation at EPRI-EPA-DOE Combined Utility Air Pollutant Control Symposium in Atlanta)
(notes on file with author); ELECTRIC POWER RESEARCH INSTITUTE, FIRST DEMONSTRATION OF
OVEWIRE AIR ON CYCLONE STEAM GENERATOR REDUCES COSTS OF NO, COMPLIANCE (1998). "The
results have clearly demonstrated the technical and operational feasibility of
overfire air as a commercially viable NO,
control approach for cyclones. The application of the technology on five cyclone furnaces
. . . .
showed no substantial
impacts from slagging, fouling, or corrosion of
waterwall tubes when fueled by western coal." ELECTRIC POWER
RESEARCH
INST., NO, CONTROL FIELD TEST RESULTS ON COAL-FIRED CYCLONE BOILERS---CNCIG
PROGRAMS (1
999):
available at
http://www.epri.com (EPR Report No. TR-I 13643).
79. H.R.
3400,98th Cong. (1983). H.R. 3400, which was known as the Waxman-Sikorski Bill and which was
cosponsored by over 80 House members, would have mandated scrubbing on the 50 largest utility plants. and was
estimated to cost as
much as $7 billion annually. Paul R. Portney,
Economics and the Clean Air Act,
4
J.
ECON.
PERSP. 173-81 (1990).
See generally
Dallas Burtraw,
Appraisal of the SO2 Cap-and-Trade Market, in
EMISSIONS
TRADING
133-89 (Richard F. Kosobud ed., 2000).
80. If the law requires a percentage rate reduction in potential emissions, cleaner fuels cannot be used for compliance,
gthe standard requires an additional percent reduction via end-of-pipe control devices no matter how clean the fuel.
See
note 68
supra.
This perversely may even lead businesses to use dirtier fuels, as it may be cheaper to reduce
pollution by the given percentage with a dirtier fuel compared to the cleaner fuel.
81. A standard such as the 1.2
IbImmBtu rate standard enacted in the 1971 NSPS would have permitted the use of
compliance coal within this defined sulfur limit as an alternative to scrubbing: but would not have prompted the
experimentation with fuel blending that led to the significantly increased use of western and mid-sulfur coals that was
observed under Title IV.
-
82. Byron Swift,
Barriers to Environmental Technology Innovation and Use,
28 ELR 10202 (Apr. 1998); Burtraw
&
Swift,
supra
note 20; 1CF RESOURCES, COMPARISON OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF THE ACID RAIN
PROVISIONS OF THE SENATE BILL (S. 1630) AND THE HOUSE BILL (S. 1630 [sic]) (1990); U.S. GENERAL
ACCOUNTING OFFICE, AIR POLLUTION: ALLOWANCE TRADING OFFERS
AN OPPORTUNITY TO
REDUCE EMISSIONS AT LESS COST (1994).
83. Marvin Schorr
&
Joel Chalfin, General Electric Power Systems, Gas Turbine NQ, Emissions Approaching
%&Is
It Worth the Price? (1999) (unpublished presentation at Air
&
Waste Management Association's 92d Annual
Meeting. June 1999, St. Louis.
Mo.) (notes on file with author): STATE &TERRITORIAL AIR POLLUTION
PROGRAM ADMINISTRATORS ASSN OF LOCAL AIR POLLUTION OFFICIALS (STAPPNALAPCO),
CONTROLLING NITROGEN OXIDES UNDER THE CLEAN AIR ACT: A MENU OF OPTIONS (1994).
-
84. MASS. REGS. CODE tit. 310,
$5
7.00,7.02 (1999);see MASSACHUSETTS DEPARTMENT OF
ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION, CONDITIONAL COMPREHENSIVE PLAN APPROVAL OF MYSTIC
STATION (2000) (requiring end-of-pipe SCR technology to reach 2 ppm in addition to dry low-NO,
burner). EPA has
recognized this
problem and proposed a guideline that would presume BACT requirements are met if a source adopts
very clean gas turbine technology without using SCR. Notice of Availability for Draft Guidance on BACT for NO,
Control at Combined Cycle Turbines, 65 Fed. Reg. 50202 (Aug. 17,2000).
-
85.
U.S. EPA CLEARINGHOUSE REPORT FOR 1998,
supra
note 71
-
86. Modern gas plants are cheaper to build than coal plants, and achieve 55% efficiency instead of the 34% average for
coal plants. This offsets the relatively more expensive fuel cost for natural gas, and the U.S. Department of Energy
(DOE) estimates that 90% of new generation between 2000 and 2020 will be gas-fired. DOE ANNUAL ENERGY
OUTLOOK 2000,
supra
note 70, at 65,67.
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
87. Because thev are more efficient than coal olants, thev also emit rouehlv
-.
one-half the carbon dioxide iC07). See
@eruliy
STATE
&
TERRITORIAL AIR P~LUTION
PROGRAM ADM~NISTRATORS ASSN OF LOCAL
AIR POLLUTION OFFICIALS, REDUCING GREENHOUSE GASES AND AIR POLLUTION. A MENU OF
HARMONIZED OPTIONS 49 (1999).
-
88. SCONOX is available for use with gas-fired turbines, and uses post-combustion catalysts to remove both NO, and
CO from the turbine exhaust, and reduces particulates as well. SCONOX is more expensive than SCR, and entails the
loss of about
1% of plant efficiency. For large units, the combined capital and operating costs add about 2 mills (0.2
cents) to the cost of a kilowatt hour, twice that of SCR. For small industrial 7 MW gas turbines, the capital cost of a
SCOXOX unit at over $2 million may exceed the cost of the turbine itself, and annual costs are $3 10,000. Together
these yield an annualized cost of $590,000 to reduce 25 tons
ofNO, emissions to 2 tons, or $25.000 a ton (note the
cost of reducing the marginal
1 ton from SCR is
$
1 million).
-
89. XONON is a system that
combusts fuel through a chemical process that prevents the formation of NQ.
-
90. DOE'S Advanced Turbine Systems program has the objective of developing ultra high-efficiency gas turbine
systems for utilities, with an appropriation of approximately $30million in recent years. U.S. DOE. ENERGY
INFORMATION ADMINISTRATION, FEDERAL ENERGY MARKET INTERVENTIONS: PRIMARY ENERGY
33, app. B (1999) (Report
#SNOIAF/1999-03).
-
91. ELECTRIC POWER RESEARCH INST., 1999 AWUAL REPORT (2000); U.S. DOE, FISCAL YEAR 2000
BUDGET,
at
http://www.doe,i~ov.
-
92. According to Environmental Business International, private venture funding, which reached $200 million in 1990,
has now sunk to less than $60 million in an era of major technology funding.
See
PROGRESSIVE POLICY INST.,
HOW ENVIRONMENTAL LAWS CAN DISCOURAGE POLLUTION PREVENTION: CASE STUDIES OF
BARRIERS TO INNOVATION 3-4
(2000),
available at
http://www.dlcppi.org;
see also
ENVIRONMENTAL LAW
INST., BARRIERS TO ENVIRONMENTAL TECHNOLOGY INNOVATION 9 (1 998) (reasons include the double
approval barrier to environmental technologies-governmental
and firm-and the fractioning of market size into
individual permitting jurisdictions).
93.
This is particularly true for COz, the principal greenhouse gas. Since CO2 is a long-lived gas that lasts for centuries
once emitted, it is critical to achieve major carbon reductions in the next decade or two. The only practical way to do so
is to invest heavily in efficiency and in modem gas-fired generation, which is needed to substitute for the older
coal-fired power plants. Yet our NO, policies make such new investment considerably more difficult, especially for
smaller units that are precisely the ones that
arc used for co-generation at industrial sites or to convert methane gas to
power. and are counted on to achieve efficiency gains and major greenhouse gas reductions.
-
94. Although a system of pollution charges or fees may also provide similar benefits if the charges are set high enough,
such systems have rarely been implemented in the United States.
-
95 Finding of Significant Contribution and Rulemaking for Certain States in the Ozone Transport Assessment Group
Region for Purposes of Reducing Regional Transport of Ozone; Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. 57356 (Oct. 27, 1998)
(covering 22 states and achieving similar reductions
as a 0.15 IbImmBtu rate standard). Although initially proposed for
a group of 22 states, challenges to
EPA's authority resulted in court orders that restricted application of the final rule to
19 states. Appalachian Power Co. v EPA, 208
F.3d 101
5,
30 ELR 20560 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (limiting application to 19
states) (deadline for states to file state implementation plans extended to Oct. 31, 2000).
96.
See, s
g
,
H.R. 25, 106th Cong. (1999) (sponsored by Rep. Sherwood Boehlert (R-N.Y.)); H.R. 2569, 106th Cong.
$99) (sponsored by Rep. Frank Pallone (D-N.J.)); and S. 1369, 106th Cong. (1999) (sponsored by Sen. James
Jeffords (R-Vt.)).
-
97. A related aspect is that cap-and-trade systems allow for efficient and smooth reductions in pollutant levels. Title
IV
provides a good example, as the allowable limit Mas lowered between Phase I and Phase 11 of both programs. However,
under the rate-based approach for NO,, all boilers that had complied with Phase I limits were grandfathered without
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate S...
file:lllC:lMyFileslACSH-HgiSwift%20EL1%20
having to meet the Phase I1 limits, whereas in the cap-and-trade approach for S@, the cap was simply lowered,
requiring all units to comply.
-
98. EPA 1999 COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 4; U.S. EPA, 1999 OTC NO, BUIX;ET PROGRAM
COMPLIANCE REPORT,
supra
note 56.
99.
U.S. GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE, ACID RAIN: EMISSIONS TRENDS AND EFFECTS IN THE
EASTERN UNITED STATES (Mar. 2000)
(GAO/RCEDOO-47); Byron Swift,
Allowance Trading undSO2 Hot
Spots-Good News From the Acid Rain Program,
3
1 Env't Rep. (BNA) 954 (May 12; 2000),
mailable at
http:l/www.epa.govlacidrain/papers.
31 ELR 10330
/
Environmental Law Reporter
/
copyright
0
2001
/
All rights resewed
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE
I, the undersigned, certify that on this 1 jth day of September, 2006,I have served
electronically the attached
MIDWEST GENERATION'S POST-HEARING COMMENTS:
ADDITIONAL INFORMATION
upon the following persons:
Dorothy
Gunn, Clerk
Illinois Pollution Control Board
James R. Thompson Center
Suite
1 1-500
100 West Randolph
Chicago, Illinois 60601
and electronically and by first-class mail with postage thereon fully prepaid and affixed to the
persons listed on the
ATTACHED SERVICE LIST.
/s/
W&
8
mAwl
Kathleen C. Bassi
Sheldon
A. Zabel
Kathleen C. Bassi
Stephen J. Bonebrake
Joshua
R. More
Glenna Gilbert
SCHIFF
HARDIN. LLP
6600 Sears Tower
233 South Wacker Drive
Chicago, Illinois 60606
312-258-5500
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
SERVICE LIST
(R06-25)
Marie Tipsord
Hearing Office
Illinois Pollution Control Board
James
R. Thompson Center
100 W. Randolph
Suite
1 1-500
Chicago, Illinois 60601
ti~sorm@,ipcb.state.il.us
-
William A. Murray
Special Assistant Corporation Counsel
Office of Public Utilities
800 East Monroe
Springfield, Illinois 62757
bmurrav@,cwl~.com
Christopher W. Newcomb
Karaganis, White
&
Mage., Ltd.
414 North Orleans Street, Suite 8 10
Chicago, Illinois 6061 0
cnewcomb@k-w.com
Faith E. Bugel
Howard A. Learner
Meleah Geertsma
Environmental Law and Policy Center
35 East Wacker Drive, Suite 1300
Chicago, Illinois 60601
fbu~el@,elvc.org
Gina Roccaforte, Assistant Counsel
Charles Matoesian, Assistant Counsel
John J. Kim, Managing Attorney
Air Regulatory Unit
Division of Legal Counsel
Illinois Environmental Protection Agency
102
1 North Grand Avenue, East
P.O. Box 19276
Springfield, Illinois 62794-9276
john.kim@e~a.state.il.us
-
charles.matoesian@,epa.state.il.us
yina.roccaforte@e~a.state.il.us
N. LaDonna Driver
Katherine D. Hodge
Hodge Dwyer Zeman
3150 Roland Avenue, P.O. Box 5776
Springfield, Illinois 62705-5776
tildriver@hdzlaw.com
Bill S. Forcade
Katherine
M. Rahill
Jenner
&
Block
One IBM Plaza,
4oth Floor
Chicago, Illinois 6061
1
Keith I. Harley
Chicago Legal Clinic
205 West Monroe Street,
4th Floor
Chicago, Illinois 60606
kharlev@,kentlaw.edu
-
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *
SERVICE LIST
(R06-25)
David Rieser
James
T. Warrington
Jeremy R. Hojnicki
McGuireWoods LLP
77 West Wacker, Suite 4100
Chicago,
Illinois 60601
Bruce
Nilles
Sierra Club
122 West Washington Avenue, Suite 830
Madison, Wisconsin 53703
bruce.nilles@sienaclub.org
Mary Frontczak
Dianna Tickner
Prairie State Generating Company, LLC
701 Market Street, Suite 781
St. Louis. Missouri 63 101
Daniel
McDevitt
General Counsel
MIDWEST GENERATION. LLC
440 South
LaSalle Street, Suite 3500
Chicago, Illinois 60605
dmcdevitt@mwaen.com
S. David Farris
Manager, Environmental, Health and Safety
Office of Public Utilities, City of Springfield
201 East Lake Shore Drive
Springfield, Illinois 62757
dfarris@,c,cwlo.com
-
James
U'.
Ingram
Senior Corporate Counsel
Dynegy Midwest Generation. Inc
1000 Louisiana, Suite 5800
Houston, Texas 77002
Jim.Ingram@,dyneev.com
Sheldon
A. Zabel
Kathleen C. Bassi
Stephen J.
Bonebrake
Joshua R. More
Glenna L. Gilbert
SCHIFF
HARDIN, LLP
6600 Sears Tower
233 South Wacker Drive
Chicago. Illinois 60606
312-258-5500
Fax: 312-258-5600
szabel@schiffhardin.com
kbassi@,schiffiardin.com
sbonebrake@schiffhardin.com
jmore@,scliiffiardin.com
ggilbert@schiffiardin.com
ELECTRONIC FILING, RECEIVED, CLERK'S OFFICE, SEPTEMBER 15, 2006
* * * * * PC 6293 * * * * *